M O N E Y Understanding
and Creating Alternatives to Legal Tender THOMAS H. GRECO, JR. < Foreword
by Vicki Robin E-book Excerpted Version CH E L S E A GR E E N P U B L I
S H I N G CO M PA N Y White River Junction, Vermont.Dedicated to champions
of justice, equity, and freedom, everywhere Copyright 2001 Thomas H. Greco,
Jr. Foreword copyright 2001 Vicki Robin. Illustrations copyright 2001 Karen
Kerney. All rights reserved. No part of this book may be transmitted or
reproduced in any form by any means without permission in writing from
the publisher. Designed by Dede Cummings Design. Printed in United States.
First printing, October 2001. 04 03 02 01 1 2 3 4 5 Library of Congress
Cataloging-in-Publication Data Greco, Thomas H., 1936- Money : understanding
and creating alternatives to legal tender / Thomas H. Greco. p. cm. Includes
bibliographical references and index. ISBN 1-890132-37-3 (alk. paper) 1.
Money. 2. Legal tender. I. Title. HG221 .G77 2001 332.4'2042--dc21 2001042155
Chelsea Green Publishing Company P.O. Box 428 White River Junction, VT
05001 800-639-4099 www.chelseagreen.com.E-BOOK CO N T EN T S < Foreword
xv Preface xviii Introduction xx Part I. Monetary Realities and Official
Illusions 1. What’s the Matter with Money? 3 Symptoms of Disease 4 Three
Ways in Which Conventional Money Malfunctions 4 How Money Is Created 4
Sidebar: An Example of Money Creation 8 Why There Is Never Enough Money
8 How Money Is Misallocated 9 How Money Pumps Wealth from the Poor to the
Rich 11 Sidebar: For Whom the Debt Tolls 12 4. What Is Money? 22 Definitions
23 The Essential Nature of Money 23 The Exchange Process and the Purpose
of Money 24 Historical Forms of Money 25 The Money Circuit 26 Bank Credit
Money and the Interest Burden 29 Part II. Complementary Currencies, Past
and Present 11. Recent Models and Developments 101 Tucson Traders 101 The
döMAK “Barter” Circle 106 Toronto Dollars, “Money That Builds Community”
107 Friendly Favors 112 Equal Dollars (=$s) 114 The Developing World Takes
the Lead 115 Part III. Monetary Transformation and Community Empowerment
13. Mutual Credit: The Foundation for Community Currencies 136 What Is
Mutual Credit? 136 How a Mutual Credit System Works 138 Basic Steps in
Organizing a Mutual Credit System 140 Continuing Issues in Mutual Credit
Systems 142 Strategies for Enhancing Mutual Credit Systems and Gaining
Acceptance 144 Part IV. Currency Design, Improvement, and Innovation 22.
Youth Employment Scrip (YES) 241 The Youth Problem 242 The Money Problem
244 How Does the YES Program Work? 245 Benefits of the YES Project 247
Involving Local Businesses 248 Program Participants and Agreements 249
Sidebar: YES Questions and Answers 252.F O R E WORD S ome truths are harde
r to take than othe rs . The really hard ones are turning points in our
maturation, our understanding of this world we live in. Losing Santa but
discovering that Mom and Dad are the ones bringing you presents might be
a tolerable trade of fiction for reality. But learning that Mom and Dad
don’t love each other anymore and are getting a divorce is an earthquake
that might rock your world for life. To use another analogy, learn-ing
that the earth is round was revolutionary 500 years ago but is apparently
“ho-hum” now. Yet try looking “up” at the stars and thinking of them as
being “down” (just as true) or “out” and see what your insides do. Try
thinking about sunrises and sunsets as the earth rolling toward or away
from the sun and see if e v e rything changes. When truth¾p e rhaps
known but suppressed for sur-v i v a l¾erupts, often rage, relief,
sorrow, confusion, and liberation flow out like lava from our core. Tom
Greco’s revelations about the reality of money have this kind of power
to change you forever. In Your Money or Your Life we examined certain truths
about money that could liberate people from consumer hypnosis. We asked,
“What is the reality of money to you?” Without understanding our economic
system, people could use the tools in the book to see whether or not their
relationship with money was buying them the life they wanted. Without understanding
markets and trade, people could see that money was something for which
they traded their most precious good: their life energy. Without any political
or scientific sophistication about how the world d o e s¾or should¾work,
people became naturally good resource managers, nat-ural ecologists, natural
builders of stronger communities of sharing. They did so because they had
tools to evaluate the flow of money and stuff through their lives in terms
of the amount of happiness and meaning that flow produced. It was, and
still is for hundreds of thousands around the world, a transformative process.
It didn’t involve new knowledge, but a clearer way of seeing that more
accurately tracked with reality. Stepping into alignment with the way things
are gave people the capacity to invent, in their own life circumstances,
ways to save money and liberate themselves from mindless consumption. Their
behavior, from the old mindset, might have looked like sacrifice or deprivation¾but
they all reported being happier and more able to live the life of their
dreams. These dreams, however, happen in a larger context. Personal transforma-tion
merely enables the individual to ultimately encounter “the rules of the
bigger game.”.Tom Greco brings the force of years of study and practical
application to explaining a lynchpin in this bigger game: how money is
created and the con-sequences of that choice. Like Dorothy in the Wizard
of Oz, he heals us by whisking back the curtain that reveals a small and
very human device behind a grand illusion. A wise person once said, “It
is the sign of true intelligence to look at what e v e ryone else thinks
is normal and to find it very strange indeed.” If this is the case, Tom
Greco is truly intelligent. Part 1 is where Greco turns our world upside
down. He explains, clearly, that just as presents don’t come from Santa,
money isn’t a simple, wholesome, and value-neutral artifact. It is no longer
backed by real wealth, and it isn’t created by the government or by people
but rather by banks, when they make new loans and the interest on these
loans requires the very growth economy that is transgressing the limits
of human communities and the natural world. Fully 95 percent of money is
based on interest-bearing bank loans. He says: “How money is brought into
being has everything to do with the kind of soci-ety we bring into being
and that society’s impact on the natural systems we rely on.” How money
is created, by whom, and on what terms actually creates an artificial world
of winners and losers, a world where abundantly creative humans are pitted
against one another for scarce money while all around t h e m¾and
in them¾is the real wealth to create a rich life. Again and again,
Greco tells us: “By issuing money to unproductive or privileged clients
of the money monopoly at more favorable terms, and by demanding higher
interest rates from the rest, the banking system redistributes wealth from
producers to privileged nonproducers.” From the foundations of money creation,
Greco shows us how money, banking, and finance interlock with our institutionalized
agreements about property ownership, corporate power, taxation, and the
like. This perspective allows us to see how the seeming cacophony of issues
being lifted up on the streets at every meeting of the World Bank, the
World Trade Organization, the International Monetary Fund, and the World
Economic Forum all spring from the same source. This protest isn’t, as
the media would have us think, just sour grapes on the part of underdogs
with nothing better to do than bite the hand that feeds them miracles like
antibiotics and telecommunications and the Green Revolution. It is making
visible and audible the parts of the com-munity of life on Earth that are
getting the short end of the stick¾a stick that could be a very
different sort of artifact. The hope Money holds out is that there are
other ways to create money that support social justice, community self-reliance,
economic democracy, and personal freedom. Money, it turns out, is not the
root of all evil; nor is the love of it, though institutionalized greed
as practiced among some of the privi- 6 M O N E Y.leged is surely a travesty.
Money¾in the form of complementary currency¾c a n be a very
creative and life-serving medium of exchange. Greco is not advocating a
rupture with the past. While this book is revolutionary, he calls for a
slow rev-olution. He suggests that we step out humbly by providing local
communities with a way to buy and sell some goods and services using a
self-created means of exchange that isn’t based on debt, interest, and
distant financial decisions made solely for economic gain. Make no mistake,
however. The impact of this local trading ability, if developed in an intelligent
and sophisticated way, could shift our society away from dependence upon
unsustainable and ignoble ways of meeting our needs. In Part 2 Greco teaches
us the fascinating history of complementary cur-rencies. It’s a story filled
with both surprise and a sense of familiarity. Trading stamps, store coupons,
discount matinees, entertainment books, and air miles are all forms of
complementary currency. You pay part of the price of an item in something
other than dollars. Volunteering and “house work” (washing the dishes,
cooking, shopping) are also activities that fulfill human needs with no
exchange of money. Indeed, these are all strategies that individuals discover
through doing the 9-step program in Your Money or Your Life. To maximize
the value of each dollar, people quickly learn that developing do-it-yourself
skills, creating sharing networks, being smart shoppers, and keeping posses-sions
for a long time can yield a low-cost yet high-quality life. Greco shows
that by making these choices systemic rather than individual, communities
and the Earth can prosper. Parts 3 and 4 are the recipe book for those
who would relish giving the creation of a complementary currency a try.
Will you be the one? Social inno-vations require champions to turn good
ideas into living realities. Social inno-vators willingly buck systems,
tinker, make adjustments, maintain the faith, solicit feedback, and¾as
a reward¾have meaningful lives and even, some-times, great success.
While few readers will have the will or time to set up full-scale complementary
currency systems, these sections round out the picture. No reader can henceforth
blindly accept that there is no alternative to the sorry rules of the conventional
money system. Having new road maps for healthy money in a healthy world
is as vital to our souls as food, air, and water are to our bodies. Tom
Greco has given us a grounded, well-researched, comprehensive, and fascinating
account of how money and commerce could work for our deeper values of justice,
caring, community, and the Earth. — VI C K I RO B I N F O R E W O R D 7.P
R E FAC E F or more than twenty years, I have been intrigued and engaged
by “the money problem.” Prior to that I didn’t even know there was a money
problem, despite the fact that my profession as an educator in business
admin-istration placed me in the midst of business, finance, money, economics,
and the “science” of management. Like the vast majority of my colleagues,
I had been schooled in the orthodox theories and views, but, more important,
we had taken our monetary system as a given. Our job was to teach students
how to “play the game” within the context of the rules as they were defined
for us, and the rules of money, banking, and finance were fundamental in
defining that game. Who was I to question them? It was not until after
I had experienced a personal crisis and emotional cathar-sis that my mind
was opened and I began to look more deeply into the ways of the world.
There was too much that did not make sense; too much that was unjust; too
much inequity, violence, repression, hunger, disease, and needless suffering.
Why, I asked, must it be like this? I began an earnest inquiry as I attempted
to discover the root causes of such p e rvasive problems. As I embarked
on my self-directed program of reeduca-tion, I realized that I first needed
to prepare myself for the journey by work-ing on my own faults, limitations,
and inadequacies. I was fortunate to be living in a time when there was
a burgeoning of activity related to “personal growth,” “self-awareness,”
and “consciousness raising.” I took advantage of many of the available
opportunities. About the same time, I began intensive exploration into
a wide variety of subjects. Having had my values, attitudes, and core beliefs
shaken, my mind was open to consider anew the foundations of our social,
political, and eco-nomic institutions. As my quest for root causes progressed,
I began to focus much of my attention on the institutions of money, banking,
and finance. I soon came to realize that, despite all my education and
degrees, my under-standing of money was rudimentary at best. I came to
understand that the kind of money we use today and the mechanisms by which
it is created and con-trolled are fundamental determinants of the distribution
of power and wealth in the world and are, in fact, among the major structural
obstacles to peace, freedom, harmony, and a healthy environment. My first
book on the subject, Money and Debt: A Solution to the Global Crisis, explained
the nature of money, identified fundamental flaws in the current.m o n
e t a ry and financial system, and suggested an approach to resolving the
problem of exploding debt and the social and environmental degradation
that it causes. That book also laid out the foundation principles necessary
for the creation of both a more rational means of value measurement and
more humane and equitable forms of money (or other structures enabling
the exchange of goods and services). The second book, New Money for Healthy
Communities, was written to com-plement that earlier work. While Money
and Debt focused on highlighting the nature of the problem and outlining
general principles and global prescrip-tions, New Money for Healthy Communities
provided more specific details about exchange alternatives: their essential
design elements, how they work, and how they are able to empower ordinary
people and local communities. It described exchange mechanisms that have
worked in the past as well as some of the c o n t e m p o r a ry local
currency and exchange efforts. It was intended to serv e as a how-to manual.
It identified pitfalls to be avoided, and it proposed specific methods
for transforming the exchange process—methods that are rational, equitable,
and empowering and that can be easily implemented at the com-munity level
by small voluntary groups. This present work continues those earlier efforts
in a more complete and better way, focusing on what can and is being done,
not only at the local grass-roots level, but also at the levels of business,
government, and global trade. While the community currency and private
exchange movement has continued to develop and mature, I have, through
additional reading and experimenta-tion, both broadened and deepened my
understanding of the issues involved in the process of economic exchange.
This book includes many new insights and understandings and describes several
of the more important developments that have occurred in the intervening
years since my other books were written. Chapters 1 and 4 provide a good
example. These two chapters together com-prise, I think, a clear and complete,
yet concise exposition of money. They are a distillation of many volumes
and reveal the simple essence of money. Another example is chapter 14.
It provides a classification scheme for the basic types of currency that
have been developed and tried. This is, to my knowledge, the only complete
taxonomy of community currencies developed to date. Other sections of the
book cover developments and innovations that have occurred over the past
few years. Chapter 11 describes important community currencies that did
not exist when my other books were written. My hope is that the information
contained in this book will be widely dis-seminated and applied. The implementation
of private exchange mechanisms such as those described in this book will,
I firmly believe, go a long way toward helping humanity create a more harmonious,
equitable, and happy world. P R E F A C E 9.I N T RO D U CT I O N T hi
s book is about f re edom and empowerment, about community and relationships,
about fairness and prosperity, but most of all it is about money and exchange.
Something extraordinary is happening to money. It is being reinvented.
And this process of reinvention is sure to have far- r e a c h i n g effects
on every aspect of life for everyone living in the world today. But what
is money? Where does it come from? What roles does it play? And how does
money fit into the greater scheme of things? These are questions this book
will address. The social, political, economic, cultural, and ecological
aspects of life cannot be isolated from one another. Whatever affects one
of these must, in some way and measure, affect all the others. Therefore,
what-ever actions we humans contemplate taking must be subjected to compre-hensive
evaluation. Are they generally beneficial, and are the outcomes sustainable
over the long term? Will they contribute to maintaining and improving the
physical environment? Will they promote healthier relation-ships between
individuals and among different sectors of society? Will they lead to the
wider fulfillment of basic human needs? Will they promote respon-sible
citizenship? Will they promote the fuller realization of the creative poten-tial
inherent in each person and community? The much vaunted efforts toward
globalization of “free trade,” which have been pushed forward in the post–Cold
War era, have failed to address these questions. They are mainly the result
of an undemocratic process that gives voice only to a privileged few, who
make far-reaching decisions based on ques-tionable assumptions and limited
perspectives. Those decisions, almost e n t i r e l y, reflect an emphasis
on the economic benefits that would accrue to the political and financial
elites in the so-called developed world and their minions in developing
countries. What is promoted as “free trade” is more often an attempt to
dominate markets and exploit people and resources, as giant cor-porate
players in the game of global economy seek to continue their expansion
and avoid defaulting on their debts. The drive toward territorial expansion
by national governments, which characterized the global conflicts of the
past cen-t u ry, has given way to a drive toward market expansion and profit
accumula-tion headed by corporate and financial elites. One especially
forceful reaction, called the “Battle of Seattle,” occurred alongside the
World Trade Organization (WTO) conference of November.I N T R O D U C T
I O N 11 1999. This was not just an emotional outburst by a few anticapitalist
ideo-logues. It was a cry of pain by, and on behalf of, those who are suffering
the adverse effects of globalization on their cultures, communities, and
environ-ments— working people and ordinary citizens who perceive its destructive
impact on democratic governance and decision making, leadership accounta-b
i l i t y, consumer safety, and overall quality of life. As Vicki Robin,
who was there, reported, “The people in the streets, by and large, were
not against trade, but want the ‘goods’ of globalization to make room for
‘goods’ like clean water, fresh air, intact ecosystems, respect for non-human
life, whole-some foods and sharing the benefits of prosperity more universally.”
1 But, apart from the “elitist agenda,” there are positive globalizing
phenom-ena, too. The development of computerized telecommunications technolo-gies
and the Internet have put into the hands of ordinary people an information
matrix and ability to communicate that was undreamed of just a few years
ago. Among other things, such tools have enabled the organization of grassroots
communities of interest that transcend barriers of distance, lan-guage,
and culture, and, as we shall see, they have also enabled the develop-ment
of new nonmonetary, nonpolitical ways of exchanging goods and serv i c
e s . My prescription for a healthy, peaceful, and prosperous world is
based on the belief that it must be built from the ground up. A healthy
world requires that the focus of attention must be on fundamental socioeconomic
entities: families, households, villages, bioregions, 2 and communities
of all kinds. You cannot have a healthy body if your cells and organs are
feeble or diseased. This book is both descriptive and prescriptive, and,
like all prescriptive treatises, it is biased by my own values, attitudes,
and beliefs. I must confess to a distinct bias in favor of social justice,
economic equity, personal freedom, participatory government and decision
making, local self-reliance, and community self-determination. All these
considerations, combined with my understanding of the relationships among
smaller socioeconomic units within the global h i e r a r c h y, lead me
to propose particular approaches to improving the health of those units
at each level of society. These approaches are broadly outlined as follows:
· Cultivate functional diversity and versatility. · Strengthen
social bonds and organize for mutual support. · Set and adhere to
standards for quality of life: environmental, social, eco-nomic, recreational,
and so forth. · Build on available local resources and capabilities.
· Create buffering structures between global, national, regional,
and local economies, not to isolate, but to provide a placid “safe harbor”
conducive to the overall realization of shared goals and a better quality
of life..· Maximize the amount of local value added in all economic
activity. · Give priority to fulfilling the needs that are closest
to home: spend locally, save locally, invest locally. Central to the entire
approach is the need to transform money and to lib-erate markets. As civilization
has evolved, the work of each individual has become more and more specialized,
and, with the increasing specialization of l a b o r, exchange has become
the central necessity of economic activity. The response to this need for
exchange has been the evolution of money and mar-kets. With the development
of low-cost, efficient transport and communica-tions technologies, markets
have become increasingly efficient. Money, on the other hand, remains clouded
in mystery and the subject of political intrigue. Money is a subject that
very few people really understand. Most believe that it is something they
are not even capable of understanding. This is not sur-prising given the
shallowness with which the subject is treated by the mass media and the
seemingly intentional mystification of the subject by bankers, economists,
and politicians. Even within the academic realm there is a con-siderable
amount of confusion of concepts and misunderstanding of terms, and little
attention is paid to critical analysis of the dominant structures of money
and banking. My research into the areas of monetary theory and history
has spanned more than two decades. It has encompassed the accumulated literature
and c o n t e m p o r a ry debate as well as hands-on activism and experimentation.
I have been involved in the design, development, and operation of several
cashless community trading systems and local currencies, assuming a variety
of roles including those of organizer, administrator, and consultant. My
active, local involvement gave me many chances to observe and experiment
with various exchange approaches, currency features, and system enhancements.
My active correspondence, meanwhile, has been extensive and global in scope,
includ-ing academics, activists, and business people. I have continued
to monitor developments in mutual credit, in LETS, in HOURS, and in various
other existing and emergent exchange and currency models. The following
chapters will describe these systems and others. The rise of the community
currency movement in recent years has provided ample learning opportunities
for a great many people. But these opportunities are still the exceptions
rather than the rule. There remains a massive job of education to be done
if the subjects of money, banking, and finance are to be generally understood
and people are to have the tools they need to bring about their own economic
liberation. Toward that end, it is useful to clarify at the outset some
essential terminology and to sketch a general outline of the major themes.
12 M O N E Y.My purpose in writing this book is threefold: first, to begin
to demystify the subjects of money, banking, and finance so that the ordinary
person can understand their workings and the pro-found effects they have
on his or her everyday life and well-being; second, to strengthen the ongoing
monetary reform movement by sharing what I have learned about monetary
history and theory over more than two decades of research; and third, to
help guide the contemporary wave of development of com-munity currencies
and private exchange systems. W H AT T HI S BOOK CO N TA I N S, A ND HOW
TO US E I T This volume focuses particularly on the creation and control
of money, money substitutes, and alternative exchange mechanisms. It is
actually four books in one, divided into four parts. While all the objectives
are addressed in each and every part, the individual parts tend to emphasize
the objectives in the order stated above. I advise you to read the book
in its entirety, but depend-ing on your main interests, you may want to
read the various parts in a differ-ent order from that presented. Part
1 is titled, “Monetary Realities and Official Illusions.” It explains what
money really is, how it is created and extinguished, how it malfunctions,
and how it works against the interests of most individuals and communities.
It continues with a description of how money has evolved, taking on different
forms over time. It explains how these forms have enabled the further con-centration
of money’s power in fewer hands and the erosion of social cohe-sion, community
power, and democratic governance. This is background that I consider important
to gaining a proper understanding of the money prob-lem and how communities
might cope with it. While I believe that this part should be read by everyone,
it could be skipped temporarily by readers who already have some understanding
of the nature of the problem and are anx-ious to get to “the solutions.”
Part 2, “Complementary Currencies, Past and Present,” describes both his-torical
and contemporary currency and exchange alternatives. These descrip-tions
highlight the fundamental features, and the strengths and weaknesses, of
each example. Parts 1 and 2 together show some of the processes by which
individuals and communities have been disempowered, and some local responses
that have been effective in restoring community control and eco-nomic vitality
in the face of centralized power. They set the stage for the more prescriptive
community exchange material contained in the remainder of the book. This
part, too, might be passed over temporarily by those who already I N T
R O D U C T I O N 13.have some familiarity with these topics and wish to
get right to the details of community currency design, improvement, and
implementation. Part 3, “Monetary Transformation and Community Empowerment,”
is essentially a primer on community exchange, highlighting the basic design
ele-ments and describing various forms, features, procedures, and methodologies.
It outlines gentle strategies by which communities can establish equitable,
sustainable, and ecologically sound local economies using “homegrown” exchange
media and participatory methods for the allocation of credit and capital.
It also provides in-depth coverage of the why, what, and how-to details.
Community activists, organizers, and social entrepreneurs will find in
this sec-tion the meat of the book. Part 4, “Currency Design, Improvement,
and Innovation,” continues to build on the material presented in Part 3.
It contains a number of innovative proposals for currencies, coupons, and
scrip that address specific community problems while enhancing community
power and strengthening the entire local economy. These models can be adapted
to suit local conditions and needs. Social entrepreneurs and community
organizers will find much here to stimulate their imaginations. Throughout
this book I will use the term community curre n c y to mean any mechanism,
under popular control that provides a means of payment other than official
currency. I n t h i s c o n t e x t , t h e t e r m c o m m u n i t y i
s u s e d t o d e s c r i b e a n y a s s o c i a t i o n o f i n d i v
i d u a l s , g r o u p s , o r b u s i n e s s e s t h a t b i n d t h
e m s e l v e s t o g e t h e r u n d e r a n agreement to use an internal
payment mechanism. Under this definition, it is c l e a r t h a t a c o
m m u n i t y n e e d n o t b e d e f i n e d b y g e o g r a p h i c a
l p r o x i m i t y. I t i s p o s s i b l e t o c o n c e i v e o f a
c o m m u n i t y o f t r a d e r s w h o a r e w i d e l y d i s p e r
s e d g e o-g r a p h i c a l l y. I n d e e d , w e a r e s e e i n g
t h e e m e r g e n c e o f I n t e r n e t - b a s e d c o m m u-n i t
i e s i n w h i c h t h e t r a n s a c t i o n s t a k e p l a c e i n
c y b e r s p a c e a n d p a r t i c i p a n t s a r e s c a t t e r e
d a l l o v e r t h e w o r l d . I t i s n o t h a r d t o i m a g i n
e a p a y m e n t s y s t e m t h a t i s g l o b a li ns c o p ea n db
e y o n dt h ec o n t r o lo fa n yg o v e r n m e n to r b a n k .T h
e r eh a v e already beensome interesting experiments with so-callede-cash
orcyber cash. A community currency need not take the form of paper notes.
It can be as simple as a set of account pages in a notebook in which the
values of trades are recorded. Such a book is called a l e d g e r, and
the c u rre n c y, in that case, consists of the numbers that comprise
the members’ account balances. In essence, then, a community currency means
that members of the group empower themselves to create their own “money,”
which they agree to use in paying for purchases made among themselves.
My hope is that readers will quickly grasp the enormous power inherent
in these cooperative and democratic exchange arrangements and that the
infor-mation and ideas contained in this book will prove useful to others
who share my dream of a world that works for everyone. 14 M O N E Y.P A
R T I M O N ETARY R E A L I T I E S AND OFFICIAL ILLU S I O NS < M oney
is a topic that few people understand. Sure, we use it e v e ry day and
it seems familiar; but like water to the fish, we take it for granted and
seldom give its role any notice. Yet the qual-ity of the water that the
fish inhabit is crucial in determining the quality of their existence.
If the water happens to be polluted, the fish sicken and die. Likewise,
money is a primary element of the modern economy that we inhabit. The quality
of the money we use determines, to a great extent, the quality of our lives.
This section of the book looks beneath the surface, describing the nature
and functions of money and markets, how they have evolved, and how they
have become problematic. It examines the relationship between communities
and the larger national and global economies and outlines principles and
strategies that can enable the e m e rgence of healthier communities and
a more equitable and har-monious society. It begins the process of building
a foundation of knowledge and understanding needed to design better exchange
systems, which are essential to bringing that about..Chapter 1 < W h
a t Õs t h e Ma t t e r wi t h Mo ne y? The process by which banks
create money is so simple that the mind is repelled. —John Kenneth Galbraith
M O N E Y I S T H E V I TA L M E D I U M within which we live our economic
lives. I t i s t h e c e n t r a l e l e m e n t a r o u n d w h i c h
m a n y o f o u r i n t e r p e r s o n a l r e l a-t i o n s h i p sa
r e o r g a n i z e d .I t i sn o e x a g g e r a t i o nt os a yt h a
t t h eq u a l i t ya n de s s e n c e o fo u rm e d i u m o fe x c h a
n g e , o u rm o n e y, a r e c r u c i a lt ot h eq u a l i t yo fo u
r l i v e s — o u r s o c i a l i n t e r a c t i o n s , o u r p e r s
o n a l p r i o r i t i e s , o u r r e l a t i o n s h i p t o t h e e
a r t h , a n d o u r v e r y a b i l i t y t o s a t i s f y b a s i c
h u m a n n e e d s . A s w a t e r i s t o t h e f i s h , s o m o n e
y i s t o p e o p l e . T h o u g h w e a r e l a r g e l y u n c o n s
c i o u s o f i t , i t s q u a l i t y ( a s o p p o s e d t o q u a n
t i t y ) i s c r u c i a l . W h e n t h e w a t e r i s p o l l u t e
d , t h e f i s h s i c k e n a n dd i e ; w h e nm o n e y i s“ p o l
l u t e d , ”o u r e c o n o m ym a l f u n c t i o n s , a n dp e o p
l es u f-fer as their material needs go unmet and social dynamics are distorted.
Although the existing systems of money, finance, and exchange are severely
flawed, few people understand the structural nature of these flaws, much
less how they might be remedied. Money is a human invention that has changed
over the years, and if it does not perform the way we want it to, we can
reinvent it. Most of us take money for granted. Oh, it occupies plenty
of our attention as we try to get enough of it to make ends meet, but we
don’t normally stop to think about what it really is, where it originates,
or how it comes into being. We pay a huge price for our ignorance. Money
has become an urgent problem. A sc h a p t e r 4 w i l l e x p l a i n
,m o n e yi s a ni n f o r m a t i o ns y s t e m .T h e r e f o r e ,
l e tm e describe the fault in terms of the information that it conveys,
and explain why t h a ti n f o r m a t i o n i si n a c c u r a t e ,i
n c o m p l e t e ,o r f a l s e .I n d e e d ,t h e p r e s e n to f f
i c i a l monetary system has become a misinformation system. As the tightly
controlled n e w s m e d i a i n t o t a l i t a r i a n s t a t e s a
r e t h e a n t i t h e s i s o f a f r e e a n d i n d e p e n d e n t
p r e s s a n d p o l i t i c a l d e m o c r a c y, s o i s o u r m o
n o p o l i z e d a n d p o l i t i c a l s y s t e m o f m o n e y a n
d f i n a n c e a n t i t h e t i c a l t o f r e e e x c h a n g e a n
d e c o n o m i c d e m o c r a c y..What’s the Matter with Money? 17 Just
as the news industry can beperverted into a propaganda machine toserve
t h e i n t e r e s t s o f a d i c t a t o r i a l g o v e r n m e n t
, s o h a s t h e f i n a n c e i n d u s t ry b e e n p e rv e r t e d
i n t o a m a c h i n e o f p r i v i l e g e t o s e rv e t h e i n t
e r e s t s o f a p o w e r e l i t e . Sy m p t oms of Di s ea s e T h
e s y m p t o m s a r e r e a d i l y a p p a r e n t , a n d t h e n e
w s m e d i a a r e d a i l y f i l l e d w i t h r e p o r t s t h a t
h i g h l i g h t t h e m : i n f l a t i o n ; u n e m p l o y m e n t
; b a n k r u p t c i e s ; f a r m , h o m e , a n d b u s i n e s s f
o r e c l o s u r e s ; e v e r i n c r e a s i n g i n d e b t e d n e
s s a n d i m p o v e r-i s h m e n t ; h o m e l e s s n e s s ; a n d
w i d e n i n g g a p s b e t w e e n t h ei n c o m e s a n d w e a l
t h o f t h e v a r i o u s e c o n o m i c c l a s s e s — t h e “ h a
v e s , ” t h e “ m i d d l e c l a s s , ” a n d t h e “ h a v e -n o
t s . ” T h e s e e c o n o m i c p r o b l e m s , i n t u r n , a r e
l a r g e l y r e s p o n s i b l e f o r s o c i a l a n d e n v i r o
n m e n t a l d e c a y : v i o l e n t c r i m e , s u i c i d e , d r
u g a n d a l c o h o l a b u s e , t h e f t , a n d e m b e z z l e m
e n t ,a l o n g w i t h p o l l u t i o n o f t h e l a n d , w a t e
r, a n d a i r. S u c h f r e q u e n t l y r e p o r t e d e v e n t s
a r e n o t a c c i d e n t s ; t h e y d e r i v e f r o m t h e i n a
d e q u a-c i e s a n d e r r o r s i n h e r e n t i n s t r u c t u r
e s t h a t h u m a n s h a v e t h e m s e l v e s c r e a t e d . Th
re e Way s i n Whi c h Co nve n t i on a l Mo ne y Ma l f u n c t i o n
s Conventional money malfunctions in three basic ways: 1. It is kept artificially
scarce; there is never enough of it to serve the pur-poses for which it
is created. 2. It is misallocated at its source, going not to those who
are most in need or who will use it most effectively but to political power
centers (especially cen-tral governments), well-connected “insiders,” and
those who already control vast pools of wealth (such as large corporations).
3 . I ts y s t e m a t i c a l l yp u m p sw e a l t hf r o mt h ep o o
ra n d t h em i d d l ec l a s st ot h er i c h . Why this is so, and how
it can be remedied, will be explained in turn, but to do so we first need
to know how money is created within the current mone-tary system. H ow
Mo n e y I s C r ea t e d When I try to explain to people the way in which
conventional money is cre-ated these days, I am generally met with a blank
stare. I think it is not that they don’t understand what I am saying; they
just can’t believe it. In the words of renowned economist John Kenneth
Galbraith, “The process by which banks create money is so simple that the
mind is repelled.” 1 It is generally believed that money is created by
the government, but here is the simple truth. Today, money takes the form
of bank credit that must be borrowed into circ u l a t i o n ..18 M O N
E Y In other words, conventional money commonly exists as bank deposits,
that is, balances in checking or savings accounts that are secured by interest-bearing
debt. Money is the product of a private banking cartel. The familiar Federal
Reserve notes, the cash that we use every day, are sim-ply physical tokens
of the money that was first created as bank credit. The use of checks and
debit cards is simply a way of transferring bank credit (that is, money)
from your account to someone else’s account; the checks and debit cards
are not themselves money. Neither are credit cards money, but they allow
you to create money by going into debt to the issuing bank. The main point
that needs to be understood is that in order for money to come into circ
u l a-tion, someone must go into debt to a bank. If there were no bank
debt, there would be virtually no money—it’s as simple as that. Since banks
charge inter-est on all this debt, and since the money to pay the interest
can come only from further debt, debt grows like a cancer within the global
economic “body. ” This d e b t i m p e r a t i v e creates a g rowth imperative
that is forcing us to destroy the life-support systems of the planet. Wealth
creation and money creation are two entirely different things. Wealth is
created by the application of human skills to natural resources in the
myriad ways that produce useful goods and services. Planting crops, assem-bling
computers, building houses, and publishing a newspaper are all exam-ples
of the production of wealth. Money, on the other hand, is a human contrivance;
it is a symbol created by a deliberate process involving entities called
banks. The Federal Reserve is the entity responsible for the issuance and
regula-tion of money in the United States. Here is the simple truth about
money and its creation straight from the horse’s mouth. This quote comes
directly from an official Federal Reserve publication: The actual process
of money creation takes place in the banks . . . checkable lia-bilities
of banks are money. . . . These liabilities are customers’ accounts. They
increase when . . . the proceeds of loans made by the banks are credited
to borrowers’ accounts. 2 L e t ’s take that one piece at a time. The actual
process of money creation takes place in the banks. Yes, money is a human
creation, and it is the banks that create it. People still dig gold and
silver out of the ground, but we no longer use those metals as m o n e
y. What, then, is the substance of money today? It is bank credit, that
is, checkable liabilities, or customers’ accounts. So the balance in your
checking account and mine is a liability of the bank—something the bank
owes you and me—and that is money. How does that liability get created
in the first place? These liabilities i n c re a s e.when the proceeds
of loans made by the banks are credited to borrowers’ accounts. I n other
words, the money is created when the bank makes a loan to someone. That
person’s account is credited (increased) when the loan is approved, and
new money is thus created. That person then spends the money, and somehow,
perhaps after changing hands many times, it ends up in your account or
mine. “What?” you say, “I thought banks loaned out other people’s deposits.”
That’s true enough. In their role as depositories banks do lend other people’s
deposits, but in their role as banks of issue, they actually create new
money by making loans. So banks are the wellspring of money. They create
it by making “loans,” and they extinguish it when loans are repaid. Money
has a beginning and an ending. It begins when the bank makes a loan, and
it ends when the loan principal is repaid. Now what makes this kind of
money credible and generally acceptable as a payment medium? First, we
know that everyone else is willing to accept it, but this begs the question,
why? The answer is that anyone can go to their bank and draw out “cash”
against their bank account balance. This cash is in the form of Federal
Reserve notes. If you examine one of these notes carefully, you will see
that they have been declared to be legal tender —”for all debts, public
and private.” This means that they must be accepted as payment by anyone
to whom money is owed, be it an individual, a corporation, or a government
agency. Further, Federal Reserve notes are backed by the full faith and
credit of the federal government of the United States of America, which
is credible because of the government’s power to levy and collect taxes.
In the United States, it is mainly the c o m m e rcial banks that create
the bulk of the money supply in the form of bank deposits (or bank credit).
Most of our money consists of deposits in checking accounts. About 30 percent
of the money supply is in the form of coins or circulating paper currency.
Accord-ing to the Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago: “currency is a relatively
small part of the money stock. About 69%, or $623 billion, of the $898
billion total money stock in December 1991, was in the form of transaction
deposits, of which $290 billion were demand and $333 billion were other
checkable deposits.” 3 But even this understates the matter, for Federal
Reserve notes, while printed by the United States Treasury, are put into
circulation by the banking system, which buys them from the Tr e a s u
ry for the cost of printing. These paper notes represent bank credit. Banks
give it out whenever depositors pre-fer to have paper “cash” in their wallets.
Whatever amount of paper money you withdraw from banks is debited against
your bank account balance. Thus, even the part of the money supply that
appears as paper currency begins as bank credit or “loans” on which the
banks collect interest. So about 95 percent of the money supply is based
on interest-bearing bank loans. Only about 5 per-cent of the money supply,
which exists as coins spent into circulation by the What’s the Matter with
Money? 19.20 M O N E Y Treasury, arises outside the banks. In sum, the
bulk of our money gets created as bank credit. The amount of credit money
that the banking system as a whole can cre-ate is determined by the policies
of the Federal Reserve Board. The Federal R e s e rve is a private corporation
to which Congress has delegated power (some say unconstitutionally) over
money in the United States. The “Fed” acts as a central bank that presides
over a private banking cartel. The share of the money-creating power allocated
to each individual bank is determined by the amount of deposits that a
bank is able to attract from customers and use as “reserves.” 4 As pointed
out above, banks act both as creators of money and as deposi-tories for
money. When you deposit your paycheck in a commercial bank, the bank is
acting as a depository. This money is then available for you to use by
writing checks against your account or using a debit card. But the money
that you deposited had to begin somewhere. You got it from your employer;
your employer got it from a customer; the customer got it from another
employer or customer; and so on, back to the beginning. The important thing
to under-stand is the nature of that beginning. Banks c re a t e money
by making loans; they don’t just reshuffle it. The money that you received
in your paycheck was cre-ated at the point when a bank, acting as a bank
of issue, granted a loan to someone and credited her or his account for
the amount of the loan. As the Federal Reserve itself describes it: Debt
does more than simply transfer idle funds to where they can be put to use—merely
reshuffling existing funds in the form of credit. It also provides a means
of creating entirely new funds. . . . [emphasis added] . . . a depositor’s
balance also rises when the depository institution extends credit—either
by granting a loan or buying securities from the depositor. In exchange
for the note or security, the lending or investing institution credits
the depositor’s account or gives a check that can be deposited at yet another
d e p o s i t o ry institution. In this case, no one else loses a deposit.
The total of cur-rency and checkable deposits—the money supply—is increased.
New money has been brought into existence by expansion of depository institution
credit. Such newly created funds are in addition to funds that all financial
institutions provide in their operations as intermediaries between savers
and users of savings.” 5 [All bank deposits originally] come into existence
as banks extend credit to customers by exchanging bank deposits for the
various assets that banks a c q u i r e — p r o m i s s o ry notes of businesses
and consumers, mortgages on real estate, and government and other securities.
6 This last paragraph is just a way of saying that the bank credits your
account for the amount of a loan, and you, in return, give the bank your
promissory note or a mortgage on your house. Those instruments—promissory
notes, mortgages, and securities—are assets to the banks. They are claims
that the.banks have against the property of its customers, but to the customers
they represent debts owed to the banks. An Example of Money Creation <
1. You go to a commercial bank and ask for money, let’s say, to start a
business. 2. The bank offers you a “home equity loan” of $100,000, which
you accept. You are re q u i red to sign a note giving the bank a mortgage
on your house. This note carries interest at an annual rate of, say, 8%,
and re q u i res you to make regular monthly payments of $836.44 for the
next 20 years. (By that time you will have paid the bank a total of $200,745.60.)
3. The bank makes two entries on its books. One increases the amount of
its assets, while the other is a corresponding increase to its liabilities.
Specifi-cally, it debits (increases) its asset account for $100,000, the
asset being your m o rtgage note; and it credits (increases) deposit liabilities
for the same amount, the liability being the $100,000 it credits to your
checking account. 4. You are now free to spend $100,000. You typically
do this by writing checks drawn on your account or by using your debit
card to make purchases. As you do so, the supply of money circulating in
the economy is increased. 5. As you make payments on your loan, the principal
portion of your payment reduces your loan balance, and the supply of money
circulating in the economy is decreased by that amount. The interest portion
of your payment is added to the bank’s equity and reserves, which allows
the bank to make additional loans to others and further expand the money
supply. Why Th e r e I s Never E nou g h Mon e y Debtors are always required
to pay interest on these loans. Thus, the com-mercial banks lend something
that they create out of nothing and then require that the “borrower” pay
interest for the privilege. Further, such bank loans are usually secured,
that is, the banks usually require that the borrower pledge some “collateral,”
which they will confiscate if the borrower fails to repay the loan. Interest-bearing
debts grow simply with the passage of time, but the sup-ply of money with
which to repay those loans, plus interest, can be expanded only by the
banks making additional loans. The principal amount is created at the time
the loan is made, but the money to pay the interest due in subse-quent
periods has not yet been created. Thus debtors, as a group, are in an impossible
situation of always owing more money than there is in existence. They are
forced to compete with one another for scarce money, in a futile attempt
to avoid defaulting on their debts. Like the game of musical chairs, the
system requires that some must eventually fail. Those borrowers who default
What’s the Matter with Money? 21.22 M O N E Y on their loans, of course,
end up losing their collateral. 7 The Federal Reserve unabashedly admits
that it purposely tries to main-tain the scarcity of money. It clearly
states in one of its official publications the misguided notion that “money
. . . derives its value from its scarcity in relation to its usefulness.”
8 This may indeed be true for politicized and improperly issued money,
but it is decidedly not true of money that is prop-erly issued and subject
to the discipline of the free market. If the central gov-ernment and the
financial sector claim a disproportionate share of the c o u n t ry ’s
wealth by emitting what may be regarded as legalized counterf e i t , then,
of course, they must limit the amount of money made available to e v e
ryone else. The current system is based on the “myth of scarcity,” but
the world needs systems and structures that affirm the truth of an abundant
universe. This does not mean structures that allow inequity and waste,
but structures that are efficient, self-regulating, democratic, and unbiased,
struc-tures that enhance the prospects that each person will able to satisfy
his or her basic, real needs. H ow Mo n ey I s Mi s a l l o c a t e d M
o n e y, as it emerges from the banks that create it, is not distributed
fairly, because the allocation decisions are not made democratically but
rather by elite groups of corporate bankers who are not held properly accountable.
They act in their own interests, pursuing goals that are typical of any
corporate business—profit and growth. As Ralph Borsodi explained it: It
is a sad but outrageous fact that banking is conducted today as a business
by men who label themselves businessmen—which presumably means an enter-prise
conducted for profit. In its essential nature, banking is a profession,
and like every profession should be conducted to render a service by men
whose motivation is service first, last and all the time. They must, of
course, be prop-erly compensated for their work, but this, in its essence,
should be a profes-sional fee, not a business profit. 9 The misallocation
of credit is a problem that has gained some degree of official recognition,
and government attempts to remedy it are evident in such laws as the Community
Reinvestment Act, which requires banks to allocate a minimum percentage
of their loans to local needs for business finance and housing. Such measures
may give the appearance that the problem is being addressed, but their
practical effect is minuscule. In recent years, locally owned banks have
been increasingly acquired and merged into ever larger holding companies.
Credit allocation policies and lending decisions have been increas-ingly
shifted to remote home offices, and many communities are being starv e
d.What’s the Matter with Money? 23 for capital as the savings of the community
have been sent to other regions and other countries in search of higher
returns. Recent deregulation of banking, which allows banks to engage in
a wider variety of financial activities, is likely to intensify this problem.
Banking, always a flawed servant of the community, is today no longer a
member of the community but a remotely controlled finan-cial engine less
concerned about local needs and more singly obsessed with the bottom line.
The greatest abuses, however, derive from the politicization of money,
bank-ing, and finance. Private banking interests and the central government
have become intertwined and mutually dependent. In return for its privileged
posi-tion, the banking cartel must assure that the central government is
able to bor-row and spend virtually any amount of money it wishes. The
banking system, despite its public rhetoric about the importance of fiscal
responsibility, will always “float” the necessary budget deficits of the
central government, by “monetizing” the debt. What this means is that the
banking system will create enough new money to allow the market to absorb
the new government bonds that must be issued to finance the deficit. Thus,
it allows the government to spend as much as it wishes without raising
taxes directly. The most destructive aspect of this almost limitless power
to spend is that, as E. C. Riegel has written, “it permits ambitious or
designing or fanatical men who are in control of gov-ernment to light the
fires of war.” 10 If governments were required first to come to the people
to obtain the money to fight, there would be few if any wars. The effect
on the economy of monetizing government debt is that it causes a general
increase in prices. This phenomenon is called “inflation,” which has been
called a “hidden tax.” As the well-known economist Milton Fried-man argues,
“inflation is a monetary phenomenon.” This means that the increase in prices
is not due to goods and services being worth more but to the money being
worth less. Economists often argue that inflation is caused by too much
money in circula-t i o n . This would seem to refute my contention that
money is chronically in short supply. The answer to this is that inflation
is n o t caused by the amount of money per se but by the fact that some
of the money in circulation is improperly issued and misallocated. Such
is the case when the banking sys-tem “monetizes” the government debt, as
described above. We can think of that money as counterfeit, albeit legal
counterfeit. It is spent into the economy without putting more goods and
services into the marketplace; thus, as it is commonly put, “there is too
much money chasing too few goods.” Merchants, sensing this presence of
excess (bogus) money, increase their prices to com-pensate. Other players
in the economy (suppliers, workers, and so forth) fol-low suit to the extent
that their market power allows. The phenomenon of inflation, along with
that of deflation, will be discussed more thoroughly in chapter 9..In our
economy, the people have been cut out of the most important deci-sion process,
that of determining how the aggregate wealth of the nation, the fruits
of every o n e ’s labor, will be spent. Some of the abuses that result
are massive expenditures for weapons; military interventions; “foreign
aid” to support client governments; and bailouts of corporations and third-world
governments, which benefit mainly the banks and the wealthy well-connected
few while increasing the gap between rich and poor. H ow Mo ne y Pu mps
Wea l t h f r o m t he Po o r t o t he Ri c h When I say that money pumps
wealth from the poor to the rich, I speak not of the very poor, who have
little or no wealth-producing capacity, but of the vast majority of people
who work for a living but have little or no financial “net worth.” The
“debt trap” is the bane of that class of people. Debt within the cur-rent
system is destructive in two ways, first because of the interest (usury)
that must be paid for the use of money (bank credit), and second, because
of the collateral that must be forfeited when the debtor is unable to make
repay-m e n t . 1 1 The chronic insufficiency of money assures that there
will inevitably be some forfeitures. It is interesting to note that the
word m o rt g a g e derives from roots that mean “death pledge,” a kind
of gamble. It is almost impossible any-more for a family to acquire a home
without undertaking the “death gam-ble.” My grandfather, along with countless
others, lost that gamble and his home during the Great Depression, when
because of unemployment he was unable to make his mortgage payments to
the bank. If information is the essential quality of money, then the next
logical ques-tion is, What kind of information does it, and should it,
carry? The answer that immediately presents itself is that money should
carry information about “merit.” If money allows its possessor to claim
wealth from the community, what is the basis for that claim? The possession
of money should be evidence that the possessor has delivered value to the
community (in the form of goods and services) and is therefore entitled
to receive back a like amount of value. If money is improperly issued,
though, the information that it carries is pol-luted at the very source.
By issuing money to unproductive or privileged clients of the money monopoly
at more favorable terms, and by demanding higher interest rates from the
rest, the banking system redistributes wealth from pro-ducers to privileged
nonproducers. The consistent pattern of official action over the past several
decades has been to concentrate economic power by centralizing control
over the medium of exchange, limiting access to it, and charging exorbitant
prices (in the form of interest/usury) for its use. Money carries information,
but the present monetary system is dysfunctional because it carries flawed
information. 24 M O N E Y.For Whom the Debt Tolls < No debtor is an
island, paying interest all alone. Everybody pays the cost of inter-est,
even those who do not borrow dire c t l y. Interest costs are included
in the price of everything we buy, whether the goods or services are provided
by the busi-ness sector or the government. The production of whatever we
buy must be financed in some way, and interest is the cost of using financial
capital. Marg r i t Kennedy gives examples that show the percentage of
the costs that go to pay i n t e rest on capital. Though her examples are
drawn from her native Germ a n y, it is clear that the pattern would be
similar for all industrial nations, since their mon-etary and financial
structures are all basically the same. Kennedy shows that the costs of
interest on capital in the 1980s, as a per-centage of the fees paid by
users, were 12% for garbage collection, 38% for w a t e r, 47% for sewers,
and a whopping 77% of rents paid for public housing. 1 S h e also compares
the interest paid and the interest gained (as income) for the popu-lation
of what were then West German households divided into ten diff e re n t
income groups of equal size. This comparison indicates, as expected, that
the lower income groups, because they tended to be net debtors, paid much
more i n t e rest on their debts than they gained in interest on their
investments. Indeed, the 80% of households having lower incomes, on average,
paid more interest on their debts than they gained in interest on their
investments. The highest 10% gained about twice as much interest as they
paid, and the richest of those gained progressively more. 2 Lending money
at interest, either directly or through financial interm e d i a r i e
s , is one of the primary mechanisms by which the rich get richer and the
poor get poorer. What’s the Matter with Money? 25.2. Community Currency
and the New World Order 13 Why Community Currencies? 13 The New World Order
14 Gaia Consciousness and Human Unity 15 Correcting Past Errors 16 3. The
Power and Place of Money 18 The Power Inherent in Money 18 The Place of
Money in Human Interaction 19 The Body Economic 20 Chapter 4 < Wh a
t I s Mo ne y? Money is an information system we use to deploy human effort.
—Michael Linto n T he que s ti on Wh at i s mone y? m a y a t f i r s t
s e e m t r i v i a l . A f t e r a l l , w ei nt h i sm o d e r nd a ym
a k e c o n s t a n tu s e o fi t .B u ti t i so u rc o n f u s i o na
b o u t t h ee s s e n c eo fm o n e yt h a th a sa l l o w e di tt ob
ea b u s e d ,m i s u s e d ,a n dm i s a l l o c a t e d . L i k e w a
t e r t o t h e f i s h , m o n e y i s t h e p r i m a ry m e d i u m
w i t h i n w h i c h w e l i v e o u r e c o n o m i c l i v e s . A s
s u c h , w e t a k e i t f o r g r a n t e d a n d r a r e l y l o o k
a t i t o b j e c t i v e l y. At the outset, it is necessary to make a
clear distinction between money and w e a l t h. I t i s q u i t e c o
m m o n f o r u s t o u s e t h e s e t e r m s i n t e r c h a n g e a
b l y, b u t a n u n d e r s t a n d i n g o f t h e m o n e y p r o b
l e m r e q u i r e s t h a t w e b ep r e c i s e i n o u r m e a n-i
n g s a n d u s a g e o f t e r m s . H a v e y o u e v e r h e a r d s
o m e o n e m a k e a s t a t e m e n t t o the effect that so-and-so “has
a lot of money?” What do people mean by that? T h a t s o - a n d - s o
h a s s t a c k s o f U n i t e d S t a t e s c u r r e n c y n o t e s
s t u f f e d i n a m a t-tress or closet? Or a huge balance in a checking
account at the bank? Or owns l o t s o f s t o c k s , b o n d s , o r
r e a l e s t a t e ? C h a n c e s a r e t h a t s o - a n d - s o a c
t u a l l y h a s v e ry l i t t l e c u r r e n c y a n d o n l y a s
m a l l a m o u n t i n t h e b a n k . W h a t w a s p r o b a b l y m
e a n t , a n d w h a t s h o u l d h a v e b e e n s a i d , i s “ s o
- a n d - s o i s v e ry w e a l t h y.” P e o p l e h o l d t h e i r
w e a l t h i n v a r i o u s f o r m s , b u t m o s t o f t h e s e f
o r m s a r e n o t m o n e y. How did we come to be so careless in our
usage of these words? It is under-standable in light of the fact that we
live in a culture in which market mecha- 26 M O N E Y.nisms are highly
developed and very efficient. These markets allow for the easy conversion
of one form of wealth into another by means of ordinary exchange processes
of buying and selling, and borrowing and lending. Stock markets, bond markets,
real-estate markets, and others make it relatively easy to convert “illiquid”
assets into more liquid form: into money. It is no accident that we apply
the term “liquidity” to distinguish various kinds of assets from one another
on the basis of their acceptability as payment in the market for goods
and services. As blood in the physical body is liquid and provides for
the easy exchange and transport of nutrients and wastes throughout the
body, money is also “liquid” in that it facilitates the exchange of goods
and services and their allocation throughout the economy. D ef i n i ti
o n s So what is money? There are three kinds of definitions we should
consider. A practical definition describes money’s distinguishing feature
in common practice. A functional definition tells what money does. An essential
definition tells what money actually is. The practical definition of money
is this: Money is anything that is g e n e r-ally accepted as a means of
payment. According to this definition, money is what-ever people collectively
say it is. Something is established as money by a general consensus among
traders that they will accept that something as payment for the goods and
services they sell. The functional definition of money is the one typically
found in the text-books, which lists multiple functions as belonging to
money. These include the following: 1. Money is a medium of exchange. 2.
Money is a standard of value. 3. Money is a unit of account. 4. Money is
a store of value. 5. Money is a standard of deferred payment. There are
many problems with these definitions, but their primary inade-quacy is
that they tell what money d o e s , not what it i s . We need to understand
the basic e s s e n c e of money. Once we have grasped its essence we can
begin to design exchange systems that will more equitably serve the needs
of people and avoid money’s destructive impact on the earth. What is Money?
27.The E ss e n t i al Nat u r e o f Mo ne y What, then, is the essential
nature of money? Michael Linton, the originator of an exchange system called
“LETS” (Local Employment and Trading System), has provided us with an essential
definition of money. Linton defines money as “an information system we
use to deploy human effort.” This is a profound revelation, and, if we
think about his defi-nition, it becomes clear that our acceptance of money
is based on its infor-mational content. T h i n k o f t h e m a r k e t
e c o n o m y a s a g a m e o f p u t - a n d - t a k e . E a c h p l a
y e r t a k e s g o o d s a n d s e rv i c e s f r o m t h e m a r k e
t , a n d e a c h p l a y e r p u t s g o o d s a n d s e rv i c e s i
n t o t h e m a r k e t . M o n e y i s r e a l l y j u s t a w a y o f
k e e p i n g s c o r e . W h e n y o u t a k e s o m e t h i n g f r o
m t h e m a r k e t ( b y b u y i n g ) , y o u o f f e r m o n e y i n
p a y m e n t . W h e n y o u p u ts o m e t h i n gi n t o t h em a r
k e t ( b ys e l l i n g ) ,y o u r e c e i v e m o n e y i n p a y m e
n t . O t h e r t h i n g sb e i n g e q u a l , t h o s e w h o p u t
m o r e v a l u e i n t o t h e e c o n o m y ( b y s e l l-i n g ) r e
c e i v e , o v e r t i m e , m o r e m o n e y. M o n e y, t h e n , i
s a n a c c o u n t i n g s y s t e m . Another problem with the traditional
functional definitions given above is that they are mutually contradictory.
Consider that money as a medium of e x c h a n g e is diametrically opposed
to money as a store of value. If money is to be used as a medium of exchange,
it should be spent; if it is to be used as a store of value, it should
be held. The ideal money, as I will show later, should be purely a medium
of exchange, and that is what we will consider it to be. Stor-age of value
is best accomplished in other ways, for instance by investment in real
assets such as land, buildings, tools, equipment, and commodities or in
financial assets such as stocks, bonds, or time deposits in a bank, to
name a few. Similarly, the use of money (in its modern form) as a standard
of value invites confusion and mismanagement. When money was in the form
of gold or silver, it could effectively serve as a standard of value, but
now, when money is sim-ply an IOU of a government or central bank, its
value is determined more by m o n e t a ry management policies than by
market forces. This issue has been more completely addressed elsewhere,
and will be revisited in chapter 6. 1 The E xc h a n g e Pr o ce s s an
d t he Pu r p o s e o f Mo n ey The process of economic exchange always
involves two parties. The funda-mental exchange process is the barter exchange.
When Smith delivers to Jones a sack of flour and Jones gives to Smith a
bushel of apples in return, a complete barter transaction has occurred.
Both parties are satisfied, and both have prof-ited from the exchange.
Smith values Jones’s apples more than the flour he has to give for them,
while Jones values Smith’s flour more than the apples he must give. Thus,
both parties are satisfied that they have gained something in the bargain.
The problem with simple barter, of course, is that Jones may want 28 M
O N E Y.What is Money? 29 Smith’s flour, but he may have nothing that Smith
wants. In that case no trade can be made. The fundamental purpose of money,
experts have long agreed, is to transcend this limitation of barter. Bilgram
and Levy, for instance, assert: “ We should . . . define money as any medium
of exchange adapted or designed to meet the inadequacy of the method of
exchanging things by simple barter.” 2 But what constitutes a medium of
exchange, and how can one trading part-ner use it to get what she wants,
even though she has nothing wanted by the other? Bilgram and Levy go on
to explain: “The one quality which is peculiar to money alone is its general
acceptability in the market and in the discharge of debts. How does money
acquire this specific quality? It is manifestly due solely to a consensus
of the members of the community to accept certain valuable things, such
as coin and certain forms of credit, as mediums of exchange.” 3 We can
see then that the essence of money is an agreement (a consensus) to accept
something that in itself may have no fundamental utility to us, but that
we are assured can be exchanged in the market for something that does.
Whatever we use as money, then, carries information. The possession of
m o n e y, in whatever form, gives the holder a claim against the community
of traders who use that money. The amount of money informs us about the
mag-nitude of that claim. But the l e g i t i m a c y of that claim also
needs to be assured in some way. The possession of money should also be
evidence that the holder has delivered value to someone in the community
and therefore has a right to receive like value in return, or that the
holder has received it, by gift or other transfer, from someone else who
has delivered value. Unfortunately, throughout history, this ideal has
been subverted in various ways depending on the kind of money used at the
time. H i s to r i c a l Fo rms o f Mo ney Many different forms of money
have been used. But the forms or kinds of money in common use have, over
time, become progressively less substantial and more ethereal. There are
three basic kinds of money: commodity money symbolic money credit money
In earlier times, certain useful c o m m o d i t i e s were used as money.
These included such things as salt, cattle, and grain. Tobacco was commonly
used as money in colonial America. Commodity money carries value within
itself, mak-ing it easy for traders to evaluate its soundness. The use
of commodities as a medium of exchange really amounts to i n d i rect bart
e r. Such commodities can serve the exchange function because they are
useful in themselves and gener-ally in demand. I may have no use for tobacco
myself, but if I know that oth-.ers want it and it can be easily traded,
I may accept it in payment when I sell my goods or services. The use of
precious metals as money is no different in nature from the use of any
other commodity. Gold and silver came to be widely used as money because
they provided the advantages of greater convenience, portability, and durability,
especially when stamped into coins of certified weight and fineness. The
certifying entity was initially the king or the government of some nation
or political subdivision, but private coinage also has historical p r e
c e d e n t . L a t e r, it became more common to use paper notes and base
metal coins, which were symbolic representations of commodity money, typically
gold or sil-ver, deposited with a goldsmith or a bank. The bank would give
the depositor paper notes that were, in effect, receipts or “claim checks”
for the metal deposited. These notes could then be used as money. They
were accepted in the marketplace because everyone knew that they could
be presented to the issuer, who would “redeem” them, that is, give the
note holder the metal they represented. Modern banking developed on the
basis of issuing paper cur-rency against “fractional reserves,” meaning
that the banks issued more paper “claim checks” than they had gold to redeem
them with. Commodity money and redeemable paper have progressively given
way to nonredeemable notes, bank credit, and computerized accounts, that
while offering certain advantages, are easier for issuers to abuse and
more difficult for traders to evaluate. To d a y, most of the money in
use exists in the form of bank credit, with a small percentage also in
the form of circulating paper notes of the central bank, which, in the
United States, is the Federal Reserve Bank. These notes, however, are merely
a physical representation of money that was first created as bank credit
and later exchanged for paper. Confusion often arises, as well, from the
variety and proliferation of m o n e-t a ry instru m e n t s . These include
what we commonly think of as money itself— precious metal coins, base metal
coins, tokens, paper notes or bills—but also deposit account balances,
smart cards, and now e-cash. In addition, we have checks, wire transfers,
and debit cards, which are not money themselves but ways of ordering the
transfer of money from one account to another. The Mone y C i r c u i t
Money flows in circular fashion. In order to apprehend the meaning of money,
one must first recognize the essential fact that money has a beginning
and an ending; it is created and it is extinguished. This is depicted in
figure 4.1, which shows money in its basic and ideal form. Money is first
created by a buyer who issues it to a seller as evidence of value received.
The money issued may be thought of as an IOU that the buyer uses to pay
for the goods and services he 30 M O N E Y.Figure 4.1. The ideal money
circuit. Money – originated and spent into circulation by Mr. Able Money
Money Money Goods/ Services Goods/ Services Goods/ Services Goods/ Services
Goods/Services Goods/Services Mr. Able Issuer Mr. Baker Ms. Drew Mr. Cook
Mr. Young Ms. Zane Money Money.32 M O N E Y bought. That IOU might be passed
along from hand to hand as each recipient, in turn, uses it to pay for
his or her own purchase. Eventually, it must come back to the originator
of the IOU, who redeems it by selling something of value and accepting
the IOU as payment. As an example, consider the process depicted in figure
4.1. The origina-t o r, Mr. Able, buys something of value from Mr. Baker.
He gives Mr. Baker his IOU as evidence of value received. Baker then uses
the IOU to buy something from Mr. Cook, who in turn uses it to buy something
from Ms. Drew. The IOU may continue to change hands any number of times
as others use it to buy and sell (as indicated by the dashed lines between
Ms. Drew and Mr. Yo u n g ) , but eventually it must return to Mr. Able.
At that point, Able has fulfilled his commitment to redeem the money he
issued (the IOU). He does this by sell-ing goods or services equal in value
to those that he received when he made his original purchase, accepting
as payment his own IOU, which is the money that he originally created.
At that point, Able extinguishes the money. N o w t h i n k o f a g r o
u p o f t r a d e r s w h o a g r e e t o a c c e p t e a c h o t h e r
’s I O U s a s p a y m e n t i n t r a d e . S u p p o s e t h e y d e
s i g n a s t a n d a r d i z e d f o r m f o r t h e i r I O U s s o t
h a t t h e ya r e i n d i s t i n g u i s h a b l ef r o m o n ea n o
t h e r. T h e s e s t a n d a r d i z e dI O U s c a n t a k e w h a t
e v e r f o r m t h e c o m m u n i t y o f t r a d e r s h a s a g r e
e d t o u s e f o r t h i s p u r p o s e . T h e y m a y b e p a p e r
c e r t i f i c a t e s , m e t a l t o k e n s o r c o i n s , o r s i
m p l y n u m b e r s i n a n a c c o u n t l e d g e r t h a t c a n b
e k e p t i n a c o m p u t e r o r s i m p l y i n a n o t e b o o k .
E a c h m e m b e r o f t h e g r o u p o b t a i n s a s u p p l y o f
t h e s e s t a n d a r d i z e d I O U s o r n o t e s o f f i x e d d
e n o m i n a t i o n , w h i c h s h e o r h e c a n n o w s p e n d i
n t o c i r c u l a t i o n . Now the originator, Mr. Able, instead of
using his own personal IOU to pay for his purchase, gives Mr. Baker standardized
notes or IOUs. As before, Mr. Baker then uses that money to buy something
from Mr. Cook, who in turn uses it to buy something from Ms. Drew, and
so on. Mr. Able is still commit-ted to redeem the notes he issued and must
eventually sell something, accept-ing as payment notes equivalent in amount
to those he originally issued when he paid Mr. Baker. This conceptualization
of money is further elucidated by quoting E. C. Riegel’s excellent exposition:
Money simply does not exist until it has been accepted in exchange. Hence
two factors are necessary for money creation: a buyer, who issues it, and
a seller, who accepts it. Since the seller expects, in turn, to reissue
the money to some s e l l e r, it will be seen that money springs from
mutual interest and cooperative action among traders, and not from authority.
That the Government can issue money for the people . . . is an utter fallacy.
Money can be issued only by a buyer for himself, and he must in turn be
a competitive seller to recapture it and thus complete the cycle..What
is Money? 33 A would-be money issuer must, in exchange for the goods or
services he buys from the market, place goods or services on the market.
In this simple rule of equity lies the essence of money. 4 Riegel conceived
a “private enterprise money” that closely conforms to this ideal. 5 Most
contemporary mutual credit systems, for example LETS, also con-form to
this ideal. Ban k Cr e di t Mo n ey a n d t he I nt er e s t Bu rde n In
simple mutual credit systems, money springs easily into existence when-ever
it is needed for exchange. In the current official system of money and
banking, however, an originator of money must first obtain authorization
from a commercial bank before putting money into circulation. Ty p i c
a l l y, this is done by making an application for a “loan.” Let us use
our previous example as a staring point to explain how it works. Before
Mr. Able can spend money into circulation, he must get a “loan” from a
bank. After his application is submitted, the bank will evaluate Mr. Able’s
“credit-worthiness” and the value of his collateral. Let’s say that Able
offers his farm as collateral against the “loan.” He signs an agreement
known as a mortgage deed of trust, and, in turn, the bank credits his account
for so many dollars representing the principal amount of the “loan.” This
is depicted in figure 4.2. In effect, Mr. Able gives the bank a legal claim
(the mortgage) to his farm in return for standardized IOUs (bank credit
or cash notes), which others will accept as payment for his purchases.
In terms of the prevailing practice, Able has obtained authorization to
write checks against or draw out cash from his bank account, up to the
amount of his “loan.” M r. Able, as before, has obligated himself to the
community to redeem, by sell-i n g , the same amount of money he issued
by spending. But, in addition, he has also obligated himself to return
to the bank the amount of money he “bor-rowed,” plus intere s t . Thus,
he must make sales sufficient to recover not only the amount of money he
issued (“borrowed”) but also to obtain an additional amount in order to
pay the interest. If he is successful in doing so, he can reclaim his mortgage
note from the bank; if not, he loses his farm. When he repays the bank,
the money he issued is extinguished. The redemption phase of the process
is depicted in figure 4.3. Note that the diagram shows a dashed line labeled
“interest” coming to Mr. Able from outside the circuit and going to the
bank. In this scenario, Mr. Able is still the issuer, not the bank. The
bank has not really loaned him anything; it has simply converted the value
of Mr. Able’s farm into negotiable form. This process is called m o n e
t i z a t i o n . The bank has used its legal authority to “create” money
by adding credit to Mr. Able’s checking account or giving him the equivalent
amount in the form of Federal Reserv e.Money Money Money Goods/Services
Bank Credit Money Mortgage Note Mr. Baker Mr. Cook Ms. Zane Ms. Drew Mr.
Young Mr. Able Issuer Money Goods/ Services Money Goods/ Services Goods/
Services Money Goods/Services Bank Figure 4.2. The bank credit money circuit
— lending phase. Goods/ Services.Figure 4.3. The bank credit money circuit
— redemption phase. Money Money Money Money Money Money Goods/ Services
Goods/ Services Goods/ Services Goods/ Services Goods/Services Goods/Services
Principal repaid to bank Mortgage redeemed to Issuer Money required to
pay interest must be obtained from other borrowers Mr. Baker Mr. Cook Ms.
Zane Ms. Drew Mr. Young Mr. Able Issuer Bank.notes in return for his mortgage
or IOU. In other words, the bank has mone-tized part of the value of Able’s
farm. The problem here is that the extra amount of money required of Mr.
Able to pay interest on the loan is not available within the circuit; it
can come only from some other similar circuit, which is to say, money “loaned”
to some other trader (“borrower”) who has also gone in debt to the bank.
Now, if Able succeeds in earning some of t h a t m o n e y, the second
borrower will not be able to earn back enough money to redeem h i s mortgage.
Thus, the charging of interest on the bank “loans” on which new money is
based causes a deficiency of money in circulation, even-tually preventing
some debtors from earning back enough to redeem their col-lateral. Thus,
the prevailing system guarantees that there will be a steady parade of
losers. This is the fundamental flaw in the present monetary system. The
example above is simplified to illustrate the point. In the real world
there are thousands of banks and millions of borrowers. The banks are con-tinually
making new loans and retiring old ones as they are repaid. In the aggregate,
the debts owed to banks are increasing with the mere passage of time, because
interest accrues over time. The money available to repay those debts, however,
can be created only by the banks as they make additional loans. The net
re q u i rement, then, is that banks must make new loans faster than they
re t i re old loans, that is, there must be a continual expansion of bank
c redit money. If there is not, the result is depression—increasing numbers
of defaulted loans, greater numbers of bankruptcies, expanding unemploy-ment—
and all the human misery that comes with it. The problem is not that we
use bank credit as money but that there is an interest burden attached
to it. In systems theory this is known as a “positive-feedback” mechanism,
one that causes each subsequent state to be, in some way, bigger than the
preceding state—in simplistic terms, an explosion, but in this case an
explosion of debt. Am I saying, then, that all interest is dysfunctional
and must be avoided? Not necessarily. It is one thing for those who have
e a rn e d money to expect a return for its use when they lend or otherwise
invest it; it is quite another for banks to charge interest on newly created
money that they authorize based on debt. In the former case, we are talking
about businesses and individuals who have earned money in the course of
their business and exchange activities. They have produced and sold real
goods or services, received money in return, and seek to make productive
use of their current surplus through saving and investment. They are entitled
to share in the gains resulting from the alloca-tion of these surplus funds
to others. 6 In the latter case, however, the imposition of interest creates
an unstable condition in which the money supply always lags behind the
growing amount of debt owed to banks. Inevitably, a point is reached at
which the private sector 36 M O N E Y.is unable or unwilling to assume
any additional debt burden. Then, a way must be found to keep the money
supply from lagging behind the growth of debt. Such was the case during
the Great Depression of the 1930s (more about this later). From that time
onward, the federal government has assumed the role of “borrower of last
resort.” Thus, when the monetization of private debt cannot be further
pursued, the Federal Reserve will monetize part of the government budget
deficits to prevent a shrinkage of the supply of money. The prevailing
monetary policies of the Fed determine whether money is “easy” or “tight,”
that is, whether the monetization of government debt will be sufficient
to provide private “borrowers” with the amounts of money needed to pay
what they owe to the banks, or whether it will fall short. These actions
by the Fed are largely responsible for the “business cycle” and peri-odic
rounds of inflation and recession. Through the various mechanisms under
its control—interest rates on loans it makes to banks, purchase or sale
of government securities, and setting bank reserve requirements—the Fed
has the power to decide whose interests will be favored and whose will
be harmed. What Is Money? 37.38 M O N E Y 5. The Disintegration of Local
Economies 34 Levers of Power, Then and Now 34 The Evolution of Money 35
Social Control through Control of Money and Finance 37 Social Disintegration
37 The End of Empires 39 6. Money, Power, and the U.S. Constitution 41
Measuring Value and Defining the Dollar 43 The Consolidation of Money Power
43 7. Restoring Local Economies 46 Healthy Communities, Healthy World 47
Two Fundamental Strategies 48 Small (and Local) Is Beautiful 49 How to
Bring Money under Local Control 50 Community Banking and the Liberation
of Money 50 The Role of Community Currencies 51.P A R T I I CO M P LE M
EN TARY CURREN C I ES , PAST AND PRESEN T < T his section provides a
historical overview of some of the more significant private and community
exchange systems and cur-rencies. You may have heard of s c r i p f rom
your grandparents who lived through the Great Depression, or you may have
seen one of the many news stories that have appeared in recent years describing
LETS, Ithaca HOURS, Time Dollars, or one of their many related off-shoots,
or you may be one of the pioneers who have actually partic-ipated. These
and other local money systems are described here, but the material is not
solely descriptive. As we try to learn from the experience of both the
distant and recent past, we also begin in p a rt 2 an evaluation and critique
that will be continued and elaborated in part 4..8. A Brief History of
Community Currencies and Private Exchange Systems 57 Scrip of the Great
Depression 58 WIR: The Swiss Wirtschaftsring 67 Legal Considerations 68
Lessons Learned 68 The Deflation Dilemma 70 Railway Notes 70 Sidebar: The
“Constant” Currency of Ralph Borsodi 73 An Early Proposal for a Credit
Clearing System 74 9. Global Finance, Inflation, and Local Currencies 76
Why Central Governments and Central Banks Don’t Like Local Currencies 76
The Argentine Experience 82 10. New Wave Pioneers 86 Barter, Reciprocal
Trade, and Mutual Credit 86 Commercial “Barter” or Trade Exchanges 87 LETS:
Local Employment and Trading System 89 The Berkshire Experiments 94 Ithaca
HOURS 95 Service Credits and Time Dollars 98 Update on the Pioneers 99.Chapter
11 < R e c e n t Mo de l s a nd De ve l op me nt s Money That Builds
Community —M o t to of To ro n to Dollars T he communi ty currency mov
e m e n t continues to develop, with new systems being launched almost
every week. Each presents a new opportunity to experiment and innovate.
While most of these systems follow closely one of the two most popular
models—LETS and Ithaca HOURS—some have unique features. This chapter describes
a few of the more interesting cases, which, as they continue to develop,
may be worth emulating. Tu cs o n Tr a de r s After a series of meetings
in 1997 that included the author and several other interested people, Tucson
Traders was launched in early 1998. The core group wanted to establish
a community exchange system that would be fiscally sound and easy and inexpensive
both to set up and to operate. It was agreed that a mutual credit system
using a set of ledger accounts best satisfied these crite-ria. It was thought
that by keeping the financial and labor overhead low, the system could
be allowed to grow at its own pace and without much risk of fail-ure or
core group burnout. While the group recognized some of the advan-tages
of circulating paper notes, it was thought that they could be phased in
later after the system had become well established. The group even decided
to pass up the usual computerized ledger systems commonly used by LETS
and other mutual credit systems and, for the time being at least, to opt
for a simple pen and paper accounting system. This took the form of a loose-leaf
notebook that contained a page for each member. All.members’ trades were
recorded on these pages. Periodic account statements could easily be provided
to each member by simply mailing a photocopy of his or her page. A sample
page of this type is shown below in figure 11.1. The name “Tucson Token”
was chosen for the value measure and unit of account, which would have
a value equivalent to that of the United States dol-l a r. It was decided
that each member should have an initial line of credit of TT200 (200 Tucson
Tokens), meaning that their account could not exceed a debit balance of
two hundred tokens. A voice-mail telephone line was obtained for members
to use in reporting their trades, for communication of news and events,
and for prospective members to request information packets. Out of the
core group of organizers, a decision-making body called the steering com-mittee
emerged. The steering committee is a nonhierarchical body that makes decisions
using a consensus process, and participation is open to the entire membership.
42 M O N E Y Community Mutual Credit Exchange Member Name: ______ Membership
Number: ________ Date Provider Recipient Description Debit for Credit for
Balance Purchase Sale Figure 11.1. A pencil and paper accounting system..Recent
Models and Developments 43 As the word spread, the size of the membership
grew rapidly, and, after less than a year, the steering committee decided
that it was time to computer-ize the accounts. However, rather than adopting
one of the available LETS accounting programs, the accounts were set up
on a standard database pro-gram. It was early recognized that, given the
geographic size of Tucson and the wide distances that separated many of
the members from one another, some way would need to be found to make trading
more convenient. Va r i o u s approaches were tried as a way of bringing
members together periodically. What seemed to work best was the Saturday
trading “bazaars,” which were held once every other month at a neighborhood
center operated by the city. The bazaars gave members a chance to socialize,
to sell their products, and to sell items they no longer needed. As time
went on, however, attendance at these events dropped off. Some members
objected to selling their quality handcrafted items in a “flea mar-ket”
atmosphere. Also, there seemed to be a number of problems with the venue.
First was the “sterile” atmosphere at the center, which had fluorescent
lights, white walls, and unaesthetic decor. Another was the location, which
some people thought was inconvenient. Unloading and loading things that
members brought to sell was also less than convenient. Besides that, the
rules imposed by the neighborhood center would not permit any exchange
of offi-cial cash to be part of the transactions. Venues that do not impose
such limi-tations are being sought. A more ideal place would be one where
vehicles can get close to the activity space and where traders have a choice
of setting up their display tables either indoors or outdoors. There has
also been some dis-cussion about possibly shifting from trading bazaars,
which have been limited to members only, to “community flea markets,” which
would be open to all. Some people believe that a more open event will increase
the quantity and assortment of goods and services offered for sale, which
will attract a greater number of people and provide an opportunity to recruit
new members. Toward the end of 1999, the steering committee began a serious
review of the system structures and procedures. This arose from the fact
that some prob-lems were making administration of the system burdensome,
and also from a desire to broaden the base of the membership. First of
all, it was agreed that it was important to recruit more businesses to
participate in the community exchange process, but most of the businesses
that were approached were not interested in joining a ledger system because
of the extra labor overhead that would entail. Second, it was felt that
some members were misperceiving the role of the steering committee and
making inappropriate demands on it. S p e c i f i c a l l y, some members
who were less than satisfied with some of their trades thought it appropriate
to bring their complaints to the system account-ant or others in the volunteer
core. The system administrators felt that their job was to record trades
and update members’ accounts and that mediating disputes between traders
was a burden they could not bear..44 M O N E Y Another problem was that
two or three members had exceeded their allow-able debit limit of two hundred
tokens. In one case, in fact, the limit had been exceeded by about five
hundred tokens. This situation was thought to be detri-mental to the health
of the system. Various ways of dealing with the problem were considered,
but none was entirely satisfactory. As the computerized accounting system
was improved and it became easier to check account bal-ances, the system
accountant started refusing to post transactions that would cause the debit
limit to be exceeded. This, of course, caused some ill feeling on the part
of those who had made such sales in good faith and expected their account
to be credited. It soon became clear that it was time to implement the
use of paper cur-rency. This would, at one stroke, solve a number of problems
and offer a num-ber of advantages for trading and system expansion. It
would reduce the workload considerably by eliminating the need to record
every trade and reducing the frequency of sending out account statements.
Further, although it would not remedy the existing cases of excessive debit
balances, it would pre-vent overspending in the future. By going to a “currency
only” exchange sys-tem, Tucson Traders could easily enforce the debit limit.
No more than two hundred tokens would be issued to any member, so that
would be the maxi-mum they could spend into circulation. Shortly after
making the shift to paper c u r r e n c y, the system accountant reported
that “the greater advantage so far seems to be a change in people’s attitude
about TT’s administrative role— many folks came to us with their personal
disputes about trades. Now that Figure 11.2. TT Twenty Token note—front
side. Figure 11.3. TT Twenty Token note—reverse side..there’s nobody to
report their trades to, there’s less temptation to report their complaints
as well.” I n M a r c h o f t h e y e a r 2 0 0 0 , a t i t s s e c o n
d a n n i v e r s a ry c e l e b r a t i o n , Tu c s o n Tr a d e r s
m a d e t h e s h i f t t o c i r c u l a t i n g p a p e r c u r r e n
c y n o t e s . O n e - t o k e n , f i v e -t o k e n , a n d t w e n
t y - t o k e n n o t e s , e a c h d e s i g n e d b y a d i f f e r e
n t a r t i s t , w e r e printed by a local printer who also happened
to be a member of the steering committee. Figures 11.2 and 11.3 show the
two sides of the twenty-token note. T h e c e l e b r a t i o n w a s h
e l d a t a p o p u l a r c a f é / r e s t a u r a n t t h a t
h a d j u s t b e c o m e a m e m b e r a n d a g r e e d t oa c c e p
t 2 5 p e r c e n t p a y m e n t i n t o k e n s . F o r t h i s s p e
c i a l e v e n t , t h e c a f é o f f e r e d s e l e c t e d
m e n u i t e m s f o r e i t h e r 5 0 p e r c e n t o r 1 0 0 p e r-cent
tokens. Any Tucson Token notes issued to a member would be debited to his
or her account. Since almost every member already had an account balance,
a way had to be found to make the transition to paper currency work smoothly
and equitably. It was decided to retain the existing debit limit of TT200
and allow members to draw token notes up to that amount. For those who
already had a debit balance, the amount of token notes that could be drawn
was reduced by the amount of their current debit balance. Thus, a member
who had an existing debit balance of 60 tokens would be allowed to draw
notes amounting to only 140 tokens. Likewise, those members with a credit
balance would be allowed to draw more than 200 tokens in notes. Thus, a
member who had an existing credit balance of 100 tokens would be allowed
to draw up to 300 tokens in notes. It was recommended, however, that members
draw out only 50 tokens to start. It was decided that new members would
automatically receive TT50 upon joining and be informed that they could
request more, up to the 200 token limit. Each member was asked to sign
a new agreement acknowledging that any debit balance, which included Tucson
Token notes issued to them, repre-sented an effective “loan” extended to
them by the members in general, and Recent Models and Developments 45 Tucson
Traders Membership Agreement By signing this agreement, I state that I
will, upon (or prior to) termina-tion or expiration of my membership with
Tucson Traders (TT), reim-burse TT for the total amount of tokens that
have been issued to me throughout the course of my membership, according
to TT’s recourds. If I am unable to obtain that amount in Tucson Tokens,
I will present the equivalent amounti n federal money. Printed Name:_________
Signature: ___________ Date: ______ Figure 11.4. Tucson Traders membership
agreement..that this “loan” must be paid back if and when their membership
was termi-nated. The exact agreement is shown in figure 11.4. At the same
time, the steering committee agreed that it would allow mem-bers to submit
requests for loans of more than two hundred tokens. These loan requests
must be submitted in writing and will be reviewed by the steering committee.
While the formal criteria for approval are still being developed, consideration
is being given to the applicant’s past account history and the purpose
for which the loan proceeds will be used. Prior to making these changes,
the membership was asked for its consent. Almost everyone seemed to agree
that the changes would be beneficial and they were eagerly endorsed. Time
will tell how successful these strategies will prove to be, but Tucson
Traders will be an interesting case to watch. The di MA K Ò Ba r
t e r Ó Ci rc l e In the eastern German town of Halle, a group has
come up with an utterly sim-ple approach to the recordkeeping problem.
They have formed a trading sys-tem that they call “The Barter Circle.”
Its accounting unit is equivalent in value to one German mark. Like most
other mutual credit systems, the döMAK system provides for interest-free
reciprocal exchange among its members, but unlike the typical mutual credit
systems or LETS, there is no central recordkeeping of exchange information.
Instead, each member of the döMAK system is issued a logbook in which
only his or her transactions are recorded. When a trade is negoti-ated
between two members, it is recorded in each of their logbooks. There is
a space for each important item of information: a description of the goods
or s e r vices traded, the amount of döMAKs debited or credited, the
updated account balance, and the validation signature of the other party
in the exchange. Recording transactions in this way provides the two parties
to the trade with instant, up-to-date information about the status of each
other’s account—whether they have a debit balance or a credit balance,
and whether its amount is within the agreed limits. This solves one of
the common concerns of mutual credit systems, which is to prevent members
from overdrawing their accounts. If, instead, there is a central ledger,
the only way a seller can check a prospective buyer’s account balance is
to contact the registrar. This is usually not possible except perh a p
s in a few very large systems that have regular paid staff, and even then
only within limited business hours. Moreover, the central account information
may be much out of date, depending on the timely reporting of trades by
the members and the frequency and diligence of the registrar in posting
transac-tion information to the ledger of accounts. This leaves overdrafts
to be dealt with after the fact, which causes a great deal of trouble and
ill will. 46 M O N E Y.Another advantage of the döMAK system is that
only those who need to k n o w, the traders themselves, have access to
their personal trading informa-tion. A possible downside, of course, is
the chance that someone will falsify entries in a log book, causing it
to show more credits than were actually earned. The system has a partial
safeguard against this in that members must exchange their logbooks for
new ones at the end of each year, at which time entries are checked by
the management group. Still, this leaves plenty of room for fraud in the
interim. For this reason, the döMAK approach will probably work best
within a relatively small community of people who know and trust one another.
Larger, more impersonal systems would seem to call for tighter, more secure
procedures. To ro n t o Dol l ar s , ÒMone y T hat Bu i l d s Co
mmu ni t y Ó The St. Lawrence Market is a matrix of historic streets
and buildings in the heart of old Toronto, and the focal point of the St.
Lawrence neighborh o o d . The Toronto Dollar local currency was instigated
by renowned Canadian author and neighborhood resident Joy Kogawa. Working
together with her p a r t n e r, John Flanders, and a small core group
of supporters, including busi-nessman David Walsh, the community currency
project gradually took shape. A not-for-profit community group called Toronto
Dollar Community Projects Inc. was formed specifically for the purpose
of issuing the currency, which was launched in December 1998 when, according
to Flanders, “amidst much hoopla and media coverage, To r o n t o ’s Mayor,
Mel Lastman, kicked it off at the historic St. Lawrence Market by exchanging
his Canadian federal dollars for Toronto Dollars and spending them with
participating local businesses.” Toronto Dollars are a prime example of
what I call a fully funded c u r r e n c y, in that it comes into circulation
when someone buys it, dollar for dollar, with official currency. (This
type of currency will be described more fully in chapter 14.) The Canadian
dollars received from the sale of Toronto Dollars go into a Toronto Dollar
Reserve Fund that provides the means for later redemption of Toronto Dollars
back into Canadian dollars. Participating businesses agree to accept Toronto
Dollars at par with the Canadian dollar. Essential Features of To ro n
to Dollars · Toronto Dollars are issued by Toronto Dollar Community
Projects Inc., a not-for-profit organization. · People exchange
their Canadian dollars for Toronto Dollars at par, one Toronto Dollar for
one Canadian dollar. · They then use Toronto Dollars (as they would
Canadian dollars) to pay for goods and services offered by participating
businesses and organizations. · For each Canadian dollar exchanged,
ninety cents is put into a To r o n t o Recent Models and Developments
47.Dollar Reserve Fund administered by To r o n t o ’s |
First Post Office to back
the Toronto Dollar. The other ten cents goes into a Community Trust Fund,
to be used for community improvement projects, or is retained by nonprofit
groups that sell Toronto Dollars to the public. · Businesses that
accept Toronto Dollars can choose to use them at par by making purchases
at other participating merchants, or they can redeem them, receiving 90
percent of the face value in Canadian dollars from the reserve fund. Only
businesses are allowed to redeem Toronto Dollars. · The ten cents
on each dollar that is held back is given to community organ-izations chosen
by the Toronto Dollar organizing group. · The interest income earned
on the reserve fund deposits is used to offset administrative expenses.
· Toronto Dollars are printed in denominations of one, five, ten,
and twenty dollars using standard anticounterfeiting techniques. ·
Toronto Dollar notes carry an expiration date. They have a two-year (or
less) life. Figures 11.5 and 11.6show thetwo sides of the TorontoDollar
tendollarnote. The Evolution of To ro n to Dollars Toronto Dollars is a
volunteer community project of St. Lawrence Works, “a coalition of business
and cultural groups interested in putting its collective 48 M O N E Y Figure
11.6. Toronto Dollar ten dollar note— reverse side. Figure 11.5. Toronto
Dollar ten dollar note—front side..shoulder to the wheel to help community
initiatives.” 1 According to John Flanders, one of the founders, the Toronto
Dollar project evolved in the following way. Toward the end of 1997, several
people from LETS Toronto met with community leaders and business people
in the St. Lawrence area of Toronto with the intention of setting up a
local LETS as part of the dream of a multi-LETS project. They found it
difficult, however, to interest the business c o m m u n i t y. There were
various reasons for this, including the internal diffi-culties that LETS
Toronto was then experiencing. In addition, the telephone reporting system
used by LETS Toronto was seen by some as being too cum-bersome for small
retail stores. The group saw that business participation was vital to the
realization of a community currency system that would have broad-based
support and wide distribution. LETS typically suffer from a lack of business
involvement, which severely limits the usefulness of LETS credits. A primary
goal of the To r o n t o group was to transcend this limitation. The group
then looked to the Ithaca HOUR as a possible model. Ithaca, New York, has
managed for several years to sustain a paper currency that appeals to both
businesspeople and individuals within the Ithaca area. It was estimated
that, at the time, there were more than 3,500 participants in that system,
includ-ing 350 businesses that offered a range of useful products and serv
i c e s . For a while, the Toronto organizers considered blending the Ithaca
HOUR model with the LETS model but decided, for the time being, to drop
LETS altogether and develop a paper currency. But because of merchant concerns
“about getting stuck with large amounts of Toronto Dollars,” a substantial
departure from the Ithaca model was made. Another of the founders, busi-nessman
David Walsh, insisted that Toronto Dollars should be issued based on the
payment of Canadian dollars, and that they should expire at some point.
It was recognized that tying the Toronto Dollar so closely to the Cana-dian
dollar would limit its empowerment potential, but it would provide the
level of safety needed to satisfy the business community and achieve the
pri-mary goal of broad-based acceptance of the local currency. The existence
of the Toronto Dollar Reserve Fund and the option of redeeming community
currency for federal currency were seen as powerf u l selling points in
gaining the participation of the business community. Indeed, the participating
merchants generally view Toronto Dollars as safe, credible, and risk-free.
Current Stat u s B y t h e e n d o f 1 9 9 9 , s l i g h t l y m o r e
t h a n 1 0 0 , 0 0 0 To r o n t o D o l l a r s h a d b e e n s o l d
. T h e o r g a n i z e r s e s t i m a t e t h a t t h e a v e r a g e
a m o u n t i n c i r c u l a t i o n a t a n y o n e t i m e h a s b e
e n b e t w e e n $ 3 0 , 0 0 0 a n d $ 3 5 , 0 0 0 . T h e r e w e r e
a b o u t 1 0 5 p a r-t i c i p a t i n g b u s i n e s s e s , i n c l
u d i n g a b o u t 4 0 f o o d v e n d o r s i n t h e S t . L a w r e
n c e Recent Models and Developments 49.M a r k e t a n d 1 7 r e s t a
u r a n t s , a l l o f w h i c h a c c e p t 1 0 0 p e r c e n t p a y
m e n t i n To r o n t o D o l l a r s . 2 P a r t n e r s h i p s w i
t h t w o c o m m u n i t y n e w s p a p e r s h a d b e e n f o r m e
d t o c a r ry a d v e r t i s e m e n t s f r o m p r o g r a m p a r
t i c i p a n t s . I n m i d - 1 9 9 9 , t h e p r o j e c t g o t a b
i g b o o s t w h e n C I B C ( C a n a d i a n I m p e r i a l B a n k
o f C o m m e r c e ) , o n e o f N o r t h A m e r i c a ’s l e a d i
n g f i n a n c i a l i n s t i t u t i o n s , a g r e e d t o s e l l
To r o n t o D o l l a r s a t t w oo f i t s c e n t r a l To r o n t
o b r a n c h e s . 3 D u r i n g 1 9 9 9 , t h e To r o n t o D o l-l
a r p r o j e c t g a v e $ 1 0 , 2 0 0 i n d o n a t i o n s t o e i g
h t e e n c o m m u n i t y g r o u p s . A “ To r o n t o D o l l a r
P a r t y ” s p o n s o r e d b y t h e S t . L a w r e n c e M a r k e
t , i n w h i c h t h i r t y c o m m u n i t y g r o u p s p a r t i c
i p a t e d w i t h d i s p l a y t a b l e s a n d a s i l e n t a u c
t i o n , w a s a t t e n d e d b y m o r e t h a n t h r e e t h o u s
a n d p e o p l e . T h i s i s p l a n n e d t o b e a n a n n u a l e
v e n t . The organizers’ current ambitions include expanding the number
of par-ticipants to include businesses in adjoining neighborhoods and communities
and “closing the loop” of production and distribution to make the currency
more useful to all players in the local economy: basic producers, manufactur-ers,
wholesale distributors, retailers, workers, and consumers. H ow Does it
Wo r k ? Since Toronto Dollars are presently accepted only by businesses
within the St. Lawrence neighborhood, their circulation tends to be geographically
limited to that area. Anyone, however, is free to accept them, and many
people who live outside the area do accept them, knowing that they can
always spend them when they visit the St. Lawrence neighborhood. Residents,
local businesses, community organizations, and visitors exchange their
Toronto Dollars with each other, as well. Toronto Dollars are fully backed
by official money but only participating merchants are allowed to redeem
them, and then only at ninety cents on the d o l l a r. These provisions
are designed to encourage circulation and to dis-courage redemption. Using
Toronto Dollars costs the consumers nothing since they receive the same
amount of goods and services as if they were spend-ing Canadian dollars.
The 10 percent redemption fee is borne by the mer-chant who redeems the
Toronto Dollars. The more times a Toronto Dollar changes hands before being
redeemed, the more the local economy is stimu-lated and strengthened. The
greater the amount of Toronto Dollars bought into circulation, the greater
the boost to the local economy and the greater the amount of money that
goes to support local charities. Ten percent of the federal dollars exchanged
go directly into the Com-munity Trust Fund, while the remaining 90 percent
is deposited in a To r o n t o Dollar Reserve Fund, which is held in liquid
asset form for redemption of Toronto Dollars back into Canadian dollars.
The main purpose of the Com-munity Trust Fund is to finance community initiatives
and groups that sup-port those who are on low incomes, unemployed, or homeless.
These funds 50 M O N E Y.can be immediately distributed. The first beneficiary
of the fund was an important volunteer project to help the homeless, called
“Out of the Cold.” The earnings from the reserve fund could eventually
offset all of the To r o n t o Dollar administrative expenses and provide
additional funding for commu-nity projects. To r o n t o ’s First Post
Office, a contract agency of the Canadian postal serv i c e , has been
engaged to serve as a central distribution center. It sells To r o n t
o Dollars and also has been given responsibility for the management of
the Toronto Dollar Reserve Trust Fund. There are plans to have additional
exchange agents located conveniently throughout the St. Lawrence neigh-b
o rhood and elsewhere as the trading area expands to other neighborh o
o d s . Distinctive Toronto Dollar decals are displayed by businesses accepting
Toronto Dollars. The Toronto Dollar currency is printed by the Canadian
Bank Note Com-pany, which also prints Canadian federal currency. It utilizes
standard security features to protect against counterfeiting, including
special paper and ink that cannot be copied. Each note issued has a serial
number that is recorded. An Example Future Bakery in the St. Lawrence Market
is one business that will take Toronto Dollars. Let’s say it has received
sixty Toronto Dollars from Joan and forty from Lee for baked goods. The
bakery now has a choice: it can spend the Toronto Dollars at Frida Crafts
on Front Street or at other participating businesses within the community,
or it can cash them in, receiving ninety Canadian dollars. The remaining
ten dollars become, in effect, a donation for job creation and other community
projects. And how did Joan and Lee get Toronto Dollars in the first place?
Joan and Lee each exchanged Canadian dollars and received Toronto Dollars
at the Toronto Dollar booth in the St. Lawrence Market. Neither lost any
money. They received the same amount of merchandise as if they had paid
with Cana-dian dollars. Their actions got the ball rolling. They supported
local businesses and generated ten dollars in donations to support community
improvement projects. The Future Bakery took the hundred Toronto Dollars
from Joan and Lee and used them to buy flour and other supplies from other
participat-ing merchants in the Market. It kept the ball rolling. Business
Benefits and Considerat i o n s Among the benefits that business participants
realize from acceptance of Toronto Dollars are the following: Businesses
gain additional advertising exposure and the goodwill of the c o m m u
n i t y. They attract new customers and additional cash business, improve
their image as a concerned member of the community, increase their contact
Recent Models and Developments 51 Recent Models and Developments 51.with
other local businesses, build a loyal customer base, enrich their home
community, and attract tourist dollars. Merchants are not required to accept
100 percent payment for merchan-dise in Toronto Dollars. They can choose
to accept whatever percentage they want. Businesses that have a high cost
of goods sold (low profit margin) can choose to accept a small percentage
of payment in Toronto Dollars and the rest in Canadian dollars, thus assuring
that their cash costs are covered. Mer-chants with a high value added or
excess capacity can afford to accept a higher percentage in local currency.
A beauty parlor, for example, has very little in the way of cash costs,
so it can afford to accept a high percentage of payment in local currency,
while a boutique selling imported merchandise needs a con-siderable amount
of cash to pay for its stock. A movie house may be able to sell seats that
otherwise would remain empty. If it can fill some of those seats with customers
who pay in local currency, it is better off. The merchants’ costs and their
administrative burden are minimal. A mer-chant pays a small initial fee
of only twenty-five dollars. There are no monthly fees, no transaction
fees, and no surcharges. The only additional cash cost is the 10 percent
redemption fee for early cash-out, which can be avoided if the merchant
spends any Toronto Dollars received from customers instead of redeeming
them. Redemption must be in hundred-dollar multiples. Toronto Dollar notes
have an expiration date that is two years after the date they are printed.
This feature provides control over the inventory of To r o n t o Dollars
in circulation and eliminates the uncertainty of supply usually associ-ated
with circulating currencies. When notes get lost or are otherwise taken
out of circulation, the redemption fund can be reduced accordingly. It
is esti-mated that about 10 percent of the notes sold will never be redeemed;
there-fore, when they expire, the corresponding amount of Canadian dollars
from the reserve fund can be spent on charitable or community improvement
proj-ects. No one need lose out on account of the expiration feature, however,
since Toronto Dollar notes that are nearing expiration may be exchanged
at par for other Toronto Dollar notes that have a later expiration date.
Start-up costs of operating the Toronto Dollar project have been covered
mainly by donations from supporters. In the first eighteen months, the
project had received donations amounting to about $25,000, plus a grant
of $10,000 from the City of Toronto. For the time being, the interest income
received on the Toronto Dollar Reserve Fund is retained by To r o n t o
’s First Post Office as compensation for its administrative services. Fr
i e n dl y Favo rs Friendly Favors is the creation of a team of experts
associated with Sergio Lub, a successful California artist, craftsman,
and entrepreneur, who for sev- 52 M O N E Y.eral years has had a keen interest
in community economics in general and community exchange in particular.
F r i e n d l y F a v o r s i s a v o l u n t a ry Wo r l d W i d e We
b – b a s e d a s s o c i a t i o n o f p e o-p l e w h o a c k n o w l
e d g e o n e a n o t h e r b y a w a r d i n g T H A N K Y O U S . I t
r e s e m b l e s a mutual credit system in its essential features. Membership
is free and open to all, but a new member must be sponsored by an existing
sponsoring member, t h u s b u i l d i n g a c h a i n o ft r u s t . E
a c h m e m b e r s e rv i c e s h i s o r h e r o w n d a t a p a g e
, w h i c h i n c l u d e s a p h o t o g r a p h a n d a d e s c r i p
t i o n o f t h e m e m b e r ’s s k i l l s , i n t e r-e s t s , p r
o d u c t s , a n d s e rv i c e s . T h e i d e a i s t o o f f e r m
e m b e r s a c c e s s t o t h e resources made available by all other
members at the maximum discount that c a n b e s u s t a i n e d b y t
h e m e m b e r s o f f e r i n g t h e m . D i s c o u n t s v a ry f
r o m 1 0 p e r-c e n t t o 1 0 0 p e r c e n t ( f r e e ) .P r i c e
s a n d d i s c o u n t s a r e v i s i b l e o nt h e We b a n d c a n
be modified by the member offering them. This service doubles for members
a s f r e e I n t e r n e t a d v e r t i s i n g f o r t h e i r p r o
d u c t s o r s e rv i c e s . D i s c o u n t s a m o n g m e m b e r
s a r e g i v e n f r e e l y a s f a v o r s . M e m b e r s a r e e x
p e c t e d , b u t n o t o b l i g e d , t o a c k n o w l e d g e t h
e g e n e r o u s a c t t h e y r e c e i v e w i t h T H A N K Y O U S
. T h e a c c o u n t i n g o f t h o s e T H A N K Y O U S i sh a s s
l e - f r e e , i s k e p t o p e n l y o nt h e We bf o r e a c h m e
m b e r t o s e e , a n d r e p r e s e n t s t h e f a v o r s t h a t
m e m b e r s h a v e a c k n o w l-e d g e d f o r e a c h o t h e r.
T h e i d e a i s t h a t r e c o g n i t i o n p r o m o t e s f u r t
h e r d e s i r-able behavior. The Friendly Favors network uses THANKYOUS
as a way of measuring g e n e r o s i t y. Members give THANKYOUS to each
other for the favors they receive. One THANKYOU is equivalent to one United
States dollar saved because of the discount received. THANKYOUS can also
be assigned to some-one simply to express gratitude for the various contributions
that person has made to the community. They are not redeemable, and according
to profes-sional accounting advice, they are not taxable. THANKYOUS do
not measure wealth but goodwill. They can be transferred electronically
or given as a writ-ten Thankyou Note to be entered later on the Web by
a trained host member. Members issuing THANKYOUS are morally committed
to reciprocate, in turn, with someone else who needs their gifts. This
reciprocity allows for favors to spread as “ripples in a pond.” Account
statements are maintained on the web. A 10 percent “tithing” of the total
THANKYOUS received each month goes to the nonprofit cause mem-b e r and
to the volunteer host member of each member’s choice. A 1 percent demurrage
fee on monthly balances above 100 or below –100 goes to acknowl-edge Friendly
Favors’s services. Friendly Favors was launched on the Web in August 1999,
having Victor Grey as its webmaster, a veteran Internet strategist and
author of “Web without a We a v e r.” Friendly Favors has been praised
for its ease of use and the willingness of its developers to consider suggestions
for improvement submitted by the members who use it. The commercial devel-opment
of a complex interactive software of this magnitude by a corporate Recent
Models and Developments 53.developer was priced by Wired magazine to be
in the neighborhood of $3 mil-lion. Most remarkably, all the development,
service, equipment, office, and s e r ver spaces have been contributed
by members as favors and have been acknowledged with THANKYOUS. Because
of its unique structure, Friendly Favors has no bank account and therefore
cannot accept monetary contribu-tions. Friendly Favors freeware should
be completed sometime in 2001 and will be made available for other developers
to improve. As of January 2001, two years since its inception, the Friendly
Favors net-work had more than seven thousand participants, living in 120
different coun-tries, offering a diverse array of professional services,
including business, career, and health counseling, writing, editing, media
production, a variety of practical and building skills, and hospitality.
According to the founders, about one thousand members have already acknowledged
almost 5,000 favors online totaling about 280,000 THANKYOUS. 4 But, aside
from the gifts and discounts that members provide to one another, THANKYOUS
are also given in recog-nition of good work that a person does that may
not directly benefit the person giving the THANKYOUS. The self-maintained
personal profiles that members keep on the Friendly Favors Web site, with
the support of a sophisticated search engine, help mem-bers to keep connected
and allow people with similar interests to find one a n o t h e r. Anyone
wishing to be included in this pioneer program can apply on line at www.Favors.org.
See the Sources and Resources section for contact information. The motto
of Friendly Favors is: “A friendly way to account for the favors we do
for each other.” E q u al Do l l a r s ( =$s ) Equal Dollars are the currency
units used in a community exchange project of Resources for Human Development
(RHD), a large Philadelphia-based nonprofit social service organization.
Equal Dollars exist mainly as credits on the books in a mutual credit system,
although members are also allowed to draw paper Equal Dollar notes against
their lines of credit in the system. Launched in 1996, the Equal Dollar
system had reached, by mid-1999, a mem-bership of about eight hundred.
The amount of credit outstanding was about sixty thousand Equal Dollars,
including about six hundred in the form of cir-culating paper notes. The
Equal Dollar program is unique in its mission of supporting the eco-nomic
improvement of its disadvantaged inner-city constituency. Here’s what the
RHD brochure says about it: “Although it is open to all, we are particu-larly
interested in promoting the productive capacity of those individuals who
are significantly underemployed or left out of the mainstream of the U.S.
$ economic system. This is a nonprofit banking system without interest
which 54 M O N E Y.provides credit to all members. It has stimulated over
$300,000 in economic activity since its inception.” 5 As a supporting adjunct
to the Equal Dollar program, RHD has established a small-scale micro-lending
program. While assisting inner-city entrepreneurs b y p r o v i d i n g
n o - i n t e r e s t s h o r t - t e r m m i c r o - l o a n s , R H D
h a s g i v e n t h e E q u a l D o ll a r p r o g r a m a b o o s t b
y r e q u i r i n g t h a t e a c h l o a n r e c i p i e n t h a v e s
o m e l i n k t o t h e E q u a l D o l l a r p r o g r a m , e i t h e
r b y a c c e p t i n g E q u a l D o l l a r s a s p a r t i a l p a ym
e n t f r o m c u s t o m e r s o r b y e m p l o y i n g w o r k e r s
a n d p a y i n g t h e m p a r t l y i n E q u a l D o l l a r s . T h
e m a x i m u m l o a n t h a t c a n b e o b t a i n e d i s f i v e h
u n d r e d d o l-l a r s , a n d e a c h l o a n m u s t b e r e p a i
d w i t h i n a p e r i o d o f t h r e e t o s i x m o n t h s . T h i
s is a new program, and by the end of 1999, only six loans had been made,
b u t a l l h a v e p e rf o r m e d s a t i s f a c t o r i l y. R H D
i s p l a n n i n g t o g r a d u a l l y e x p a n d t h e p r o g r a
m . T he Dev el o pi n g Wo rl d Ta ke s t he Le a d During the 1980s,
the first decade of the new wave, activity within the grass-roots exchange
movement was confined mainly to the English-speaking world, with a few
systems eventually popping up elsewhere. From the early 1990s onward, however,
activity in the rest of the world has burgeoned, with new organizations
and networks showing up in a variety of cultural contexts, first on the
European continent, then in Asia and Latin America. Much of this later
activity was undoubtedly inspired by those earlier pioneers, but the develop-ment
in South America has been unique and mainly homegrown. The Global Trading
Network (Red Global de Trueque, or RGT) 6 The megalopolis of Buenos Aires
stretches out along the Rio Plata; 120 miles long and 30 miles wide, it
is home to about half of Argentina’s forty million people. It is also the
birthplace of a phenomenal modern manifestation of c o m p l e m e n t
a ry exchange which has come to be known as Red Global de Trueque, or Global
Trading Network. Beginning with the organization of a sin-gle “barter club”
in an outlying sector of Buenos Aires in 1995, the social money movement,
as it is called in Latin America, has exploded into a socioeconomic phenomenon
involving hundreds of thousands of people in at least nine South American
countries. T h e e m e r g e n c e o f s o c i a l m o n e y i n L a t
i n A m e r i c a h a s o c c u r r e d w i t h i n t h e b r o a d e r
c o n t e x t o f a m o v e m e n t t o w a r d c o m m u n i t y b u i
l d i n g a n d “ s o c i a l s o l i d a r i t y ” t h a t h a s a r i
s e n l a r g e l y a s a r e s p o n s e t o e c o n o m i c g l o b a
l i z a t i o n . T h e A r g e n t i n e g o v e r n m e n t , l i k e
o t h e r s i n t h e r e g i o n , o v e r t h e p a s t s e v e r a l
y e a r s h a s b e e n e n g a g e d i n a n a g g r e s s i v e p r o
g r a m o f p r i v a t i z a t i o n a n d h a s p u r s u e d p o l i
c i e s f a v o r a b l e t o t h e i n c r e a s i n g d o m i n a n c
e o f m u l t i n a t i o n a l Recent Models and Developments 55 Recent
Models and Developments 55.c o m p a n i e s i n A r g e n t i n e m a
r k e t s . A s p a r t o f i t s n e w e c o n o m i c s t r a t e g y,
t h e g o v e r n m e n t h a s n o w r i g i d l y l i n k e d t h e A
r g e n t i n e p e s o t o t h e U n i t e d S t a t e s d o l l a r.
7 A l t h o u g h t h e s e p o l i c i e s m a y h a v e b r o u g h t
b e n e f i t s t o s o m e , t h e y h a v e w r e a k e d t r e m e n
d o u s h a r d s h i p s o n t h e p o o r a n d m i d d l e c l a s s
e s . U n e m p l o y-m e n t h a s r e a c h e d h i g h l e v e l s ,
a t t i m e s o f f i c i a l l y e s t i m a t e d t o b e a r o u n d
2 0 p e r c e n t . T h e r e a l i t y i s m u c h w o r s e t h a n t
h a t . I n m a n y o f t h e b a r r i o s o f B u e n o s A i r e s ,
a n d i n s o m e r u r a l v i l l a g e s , u p t o 5 0 p e r c e n t
a r e w i t h o u t p a i d w o r k . E v e n s k i l l e d p r o f e s
s i o n a l s h a v e h a d a h a r d t i m e . T h e s o c i a l “ s a
f e t y n e t ” i n A r g e n t i n a i s b o t h f l i m s y a n d f u
l l o f h o l e s , m a k i n g s u b s i s t e n c e v e ry d i f f i-c
u l t f o r p e o p l e w i t h o u t e m p l o y m e n t . T h e p e o
p l e h a v e r e s p o n d e d t o t h i s c h a l-l e n g e w i t h t
r e m e n d o u s e n e r g y, i n i t i a t i v e , c r e a t i v i t
y, a n d c o u r a g e , b u i l d i n g n e t w o r k s o f m u t u a
l a s s i s t a n c e t h a t a r e l e a d i n g t h e m t o w a r d g
r e a t e r s e l f -r e l i a n c e a n d s o c i a l c o h e s i v e
n e s s . T h e B e g i n n i n g T h e f i r s t b a r t e r c l u b i
n A r g e n t i n a a r o s e i n 1 9 9 5 w h e n a g r o u p o f n e i
g h b o r s i n i t i a t e d w e e k l y m e e t i n g s t o e n a c t
d i r e c t b a r t e r t r a d e s o f f o o d a n d c l o t h i n g .
T h e y q u i c k l y e x p a n d e d t h e i r e c o n o m i c i n t e
r a c t i o n s i n t o a k i n d o f m u t u a l c r e d i t t r a d i
n g ( w h a t t h e y c a l l “ m u l t i r e c i p r o c a l b a r t e
r ” 8 ) i n v o l v i n g a w i d e r v a r i e t y o f g o o d s a n d
s e rv i c e s . S i n c e t h e n , t h e o r g a n i z a t i o n o f
l o c a l c l u b s o r “ n o d o s ” h a s p r o l i f e r a t e d a m
o n g g r o u p s o f p o o r a n d m a r g i n a l-i z e d p e o p l e
t h r o u g h o u t L a t i n A m e r i c a . T h e f o l l o w i n g i
s a s l i g h t l y e d i t e d v e r-s i o n o f H e l o i s a P r i m
a v e r a ’s d e s c r i p t i o n o f t h e b i r t h a n d d e v e l
o p m e n t o f t h e RGT system. It was on the 1st of May 1995 that a
group of ecologists, worried about the impact unemployment was having on
the quality of life, created the first Barter Club comprised of twenty
people, in Bernal, thirty kilometers from Buenos Aires in Argentina. Every
Saturday, group members met to exchange their products (at the beginning,
bread, various foodstuffs, fruit and vegetables, tarts, handcrafts, and
afterwards, services—dental care, hairdressing, massage, ther-a p y, etc.).
Some months later the first club opened in Buenos Aires. . . . One year
later, a television program gave a great impulse to further growth, which
up to then had been rather slow and led by the early pioneers. The accounts,
which from the outset had been recorded in a centralized notebook, were
soon com-puterized because of the increase in the number of transactions.
Sometime l a t e r, a system of cheques was set up—similar to the French
SEL system. 9 H o w-e v e r, people quickly began using these cheques as
currency for other transac-tions, endorsing them and using them to pay
for purchases. This was possible because the people knew each other and
could trust the vouchers (cheques) coming from a friend or trusted acquaintance.
This was how the first ticket trueque (an exchange voucher) came into being,
which was transferable to any-one that was part of the system. Right from
the start the units were called cred-itos because of their association
with the trust that existed between participants 56 M O N E Y.Recent Models
and Developments 57 [each credito or credit is equivalent in value to one
Argentine peso, which is equivalent to one U.S. dollar]. On becoming a
member of the club, each par-ticipant would receive the same number of
credits, thus encouraging and greatly multiplying the speed of transactions.
Since everyone receives the same number of credits, the initial “equality”
surprises new members, and at the same time stimulates the creation of
new clubs. Since each member must produce and consume to be in the system,
they are called “prosumers,” a term suggested by Alvin Toffler’s Third
Wave. Thus it was that two years later it was possible to find groups organized
in dif-ferent regions of Greater Buenos Aires as well as in the interior
of the country. A form of administration linking the groups soon turned
out to be necessary in view of the complexity of the exchanges that took
place between members of different clubs, which is the richest aspect of
the network. So the Barter Net-work came into being, with the clubs starting
to call themselves nodos (knots). This central government enabled equality
to be maintained between the groups and the members of those groups. The
founding group defined some ethical principles, but without doubt each
autonomous group has freely interpreted them. Today there exist a great
number of interconnected groups, but also many others that are completely
independent of the founding group. Although the media was responsible for
the initial spread of this initiative, it was the city government of Buenos
Aires that provided the first government support, firstly, from the Department
of Social Affairs, and afterwards from the Department of Industry, Trade
and Com-merce. This attitude encouraged other towns to do the same and
five years later there are more than forty that have given their backing
to similar initiatives, in one way or another. Within three years of its
creation, the Red Global de Trueque had grown to more than 100,000 members.
Representatives were invited to Helsinki to show this experiment to other
community activists who were working to ameliorate the negative effects
of economic globalization. The members of the Network therefore started
to see their success (speed of growth, numbers of active mem-bers, for
example) in an entirely new light. Various training systems were set up
and diffusion throughout other Latin American countries began on a sys-tematic
basis, all within the context of creating a critical mass, political visibility,
variety in the experiments, and to join together with other forms of the
Econ-omy of Solidarity. The Present By the early part of 2001, “nodos”
or trading clubs had been set up in fourteen Argentine provinces and eight
other countries of South and Central American, including Bolivia, Brazil,
Chile, Colombia, Ecuador, El Sal-v a d o r, Peru, and Uruguay. Creditos
now take the form of a great assortment of “papelitos” 1 0 or paper notes,
which are printed by the larger clubs and issued to the new members of
new or existing clubs. While firm statistics are not avail-able, it is
estimated that within Argentina alone there are between 500 and.58 M O
N E Y 1,000 trading clubs with a total combined membership of more than
300,000. Many of these are family memberships involving several people.
Further, cred-itos notes are circulated among nonmembers as well, so that
the number of active participants in this parallel economy is much greater,
perhaps as high as half a million people. According to Primavera, the circulation
of creditos notes “provides, on average, between one and four minimum wages
(about 300 U.S. dollars per month) per family; public tax returns have
multiplied as a result of private agreements held by governments with individual
prosumers from which products or services are accepted, and a judge has
even authorized the payment of a living allowance in social money!” A large
proportion of the trading using these community currencies takes place
at local trading fairs that are held at regularly scheduled times, some
once or twice a week, others much more frequently. I was told by one of
the movement leaders that on any given day, approximately twenty trading
fairs are going on in various clubs around the country. In April 2001 I
went to Argentina, where I visited several trading clubs around greater
Buenos Aires and had an opportunity to observe a few of their trading fairs.
One of them, held in the “west zone,” was particularly impressive. It was
held on a We d n e s-day afternoon in a large community center and involved
upwards of four hun-dred people buying and selling. The atmosphere of excitement
and vitality was truly astonishing, and not a single peso or dollar was
involved in any of the thousands of transactions that were made. Instead,
one could see a variety of paper notes passing from hand to hand. These
were the creditos notes issued by the clubs in this zone, as well as those
issued in several other zones. Figure 11.7 shows a few of these notes.
Within the trading fairs, no official money is exchanged. Pesos and dollars
are not permitted because of the tax implica-tions. Argentina has a value
added tax (VAT), which is a kind of sales tax. As long as no official money
is involved, trades are not taxed. What people do out-side the fairs is,
of course, a personal matter between the buyer and the seller. Another
club, located in a poor neighborhood, operates out of a former f a c t
o ry building. It is open for trading seven hours a day, six days a week.
It was organized in the year 2000 by two men from the community and is
presently administered by a team of three people who have complete respon-sibility
and control. Member participation is insignificant. This nodo does not
issue its own notes but utilizes the notes issued by other nodos. The organizers
have recently taken a five-year lease on the factory prop-erty for a monthly
rental fee of 2,500 pesos (equivalent to U.S.$2,500). It is a large property
that includes a huge main building, a more modest sized out-building, a
parking lot, and a very large adjacent field. During our two-hour visit
to one of their trading fairs we estimated there must have been about three
hundred people buying and selling. We were told that on the previous day
more than two thousand people had passed through..Figure 11-7. Various
currency notes used within Argentina’s Red Global de Trueque network..T
h e c o s t s o f o p e r a t i o n o ft h e c e n t e r a r e c o v e
r e d b y a d m i s s i o n f e e s , w h i c h a r e 2 0 c e n t a v o
s ( 2 0 c e n t s ) p l u s o n e h a l f a c r e d i t o . A s s u m i
n g a m o d e s t f i g u r e o f 5 0 0 p a i d a d m i s s i o n s p e
r d a y a n d 2 5 d a y s o f o p e r a t i o n m o n t h l y, e s t i
m a t e d t o t a l m o n t h l yr e v e n u e sw o u l da m o u n tt o2
, 5 0 0p e s o s( d o l l a r s )a n d6 , 2 5 0c r e d i t o s .T h i s
i s e n o u g h t o p a y t h e r e n t , w h i c h m u s t b e p a i d
i n p e s o s , a n d t o p a y t h e o r g a n i z-e r s a n d t h e i
r h e l p e r s i n c r e d i t o s t o a d m i n i s t e r a n dm a i
n t a i n t h e o p e r a t i o n .O n e w o u l d p r e s u m e t h a
t u t i l i t i e s m u s t a l s o b e p a i d i n p e s o s a n d t h
a t t h i s a m o u n t o f a c t i v i t y w o u l d n o t p r o v i d
e s u f f i c i e n t p e s o i n c o m e t o m e e t t h a t e x p e n
s e . T h e a d m i n i s t r a t o r s t o l d u s , h o w e v e r, t
h a t t h e i r e a r l y f a i r s h a d b e e n a l m o s t o v e r-w
h e l m e d b y t h r o n g s o f p e o p l e , w h i c h t h e y n u m
b e r e d i n t h e t h o u s a n d s . B a s e d o n t h a t e x p e r
i e n c e , t h e y e s t i m a t e t h a t t h e i r m e m b e r s h i
p w i l l s o o n r e a c h 1 0 , 0 0 0 a n d t h e y e x p e c t t oh
a v e n o p r o b l e m s r a i s i n gt h e p e s o i n c o m et h e y
n e e d . We were also told that when they do have surplus peso income
they use it to buy goods in the formal market to be sold for creditos in
the trading fairs. These goods consist mainly of basic foods and ingredients,
such as meat, veg-etables, fruit, oil, wheat, eggs, and sugar. This practice
effectively links the resources available in the formal (peso) market with
the income-earning pos-sibilities of the trueque (creditos) market without
suffering the negative effects that would result from a direct currency
exchange. The organizers told us of their plans for the various resources
at their dis-posal on the site. They intend to continue using the main
building for the daily trading fairs. They plan to convert half of the
outbuilding into production spaces, such as woodworking shops, and to utilize
the other half as classroom space for training people in basic skills.
The adjacent field, which is covered with grass and has several large trees,
will be made into a campground. O rganization and Operation Each nodo or
club is autonomous and is responsible for its own organization, administration,
budget, and finances. The Network has no centralized administration, only
regular monthly meetings within each zone and a monthly interzonal meeting.
At present, clubs follow several models of organization and the issuance
of the currency notes is not uni-form. Administrative costs are covered
in different ways by the different clubs. Some impose a monthly membership
fee while others, such as the one described above, require buyers and sellers
to pay a small admission fee to par-ticipate in the many trading fairs.
Some nodos are organized with an emphasis on building social solidarity
among their members, while others are organized mainly as an economic expedient
to provide a way for cash-poor people to meet their material needs. The
former are more participatory, while the latter tend to be more paternalistically
administered by a core group of organizers. The network provides marginalized
people with opportunities they cannot find in the formal market economy.
It is not seen as a substitute for the for-mal economy, but as a parallel
and complementary economy. While helping 60 M O N E Y 60 M O N E Y.people
to satisfy their immediate needs, it also gives them an opportunity to
develop confidence, skills, products, and services that can also enable
them to function in the formal economy. All kinds of goods and services
are to be found within the barter clubs, including bakers, dentists, bricklayers,
and other tradespeople and profes-sionals who can’t find a place in the
labor market. Reliable statistics do not exist, but estimates of the total
amount of creditos that have been issued by all the clubs in Argentina
range from around 6 million on up. Currently, the volume of trading within
this barter network amounts to a minimum of 800 million pesos (equal to
800 million U.S. dollars) annually. The National Government Offers Support
The national government of Argentina has officially recognized the value
and usefulness of “barter” exchange as a weapon against unemployment and
has lent its support to the promotion of “multireciprocal exchange of goods
and services” throughout the country. In December 2000, the government
of Argentina signed an agree-ment with Red Global de Tr u e q u e . 1 1
Among the specific items of support is a commitment by the government to
assist the network to develop its organiza-tional infrastructure to help
it reach larger numbers of people across a wider area of the country. The
government will help to promote interregional exchange by means of an Internet-based
communications system that will link the various clubs in the network.
They hope that this “partnership” can pro-mote the formation of efficient
enterprises that contribute to the creation of jobs and enable marginalized
workers to develop skills and tools that may permit their entry into the
“productive tissue” of the economy. The govern-ment has stated its clear
intention to help, but not force, participants into the mainstream economy.
It has committed to provide training and support that will assist “the
gradual and orderly transition of the prosumers circuit ruled by social
money (vouchers), toward the formal economy’s area, building gen-uine ventures,”
but it will allow prosumers to continue their participation in the barter
circuit, as they wish. “We believe this network has had a great development
but very low profile. Now we want to give it a better organization on the
national level and use it as a good tool for development,” said Secretary
of Small and Middle-sized Enter-prises Enrique Martinez. Martinez thinks
that “barter has been built as an ele-ment that jobless people recognize
as a transition step toward the formal economy, or a substitute. From barter,
people feel encouraged again. We can-not be absent from such a rich project.”
The dual goal of the government is, on the one hand, to establish and expand
the barter of goods and services as a substitute for the formal economic
system, while, on the other hand, to make it easy for such people to go
back into the labor market. Whether or not this government involvement
will prove helpful remains to be seen. Recent Models and Developments 61.Close
observers point to a number of factors contributing to the success of RGT.
Among these are: · The regular membership meetings convened by each
nodo · The use of only social money in most transactions ·
More reliance upon ethical behavior and peer pressure and less reliance
upon formal rules · A great deal of local group autonomy and the
avoidance of centralized lead-ership and control · Only a few shared
rules that define a loose federation of nodos at both the regional and
the national levels · A decision-making process that seeks consensus.
Some of the more active participants in several nodos, believe that the
suc-cess of the RGT could lead to the creation of more far-reaching networks
of socioeconomic solidarity. For this reason the Latin American Socioeconomic
Solidarity Network (Redlases) was created in 1999, and the Global Socioeco-nomic
Solidarity Network (Red Global de Socioeconomía Solidaria—RGSES)
in 2001. The latter came out of the first World Social Forum that took
place in January 2001 in Porto Alegre, Brazil. The focus of these initiatives
is to rebuild the social fabric and create an Economy of Solidarity based
on social money systems and other complementary economic, cultural, and
social strate-gies that address the whole economic process: p roduction,
trading, and con-s u m p t i o n, and simultaneous financial strategies
such as micro-loans using a combination of both formal and social money.
Principles As the trading network has evolved, the participants have adopted
a set of twelve principles that define the values, objectives, and oper-ating
characteristics of the associated clubs. These were proposed by the founders
and include (among others) the following: · We are not trying to
promote articles or services, but to mutually help our-selves to obtain
a higher meaning of life through the intermediary of work, mutual understanding,
and equitable exchange. · We maintain that it is possible to replace
sterile competition, selfish gain, and speculation with mutual exchange
between people. · We believe that our actions, products, and services
can respond to ethical and ecological norms, rather than the dictates of
the market, consumerism, and the quest for short-term benefits. ·
The only conditions to which members of the Red Global de Trueque are bound
are: to take part in periodic group meetings, to be involved in train-ing
programs, to produce and consume goods, services, and knowledge 62 M O
N E Y.available within the Network, in the spirit of the recommendations
of the various Circles of Quality and Mutual Aid. · We believe that
it is possible to combine group autonomy in the adminis-tration of its
internal affairs with the fundamental ethical principles of the Network.
Over the past few years, the Latin American Socioeconomic Solidarity Net-work
has debated adopting a thirteenth principle regarding whether, and how,
the club organizers should be compensated. Discussions have led to consider-ation
of the role of volunteer help overall. There seems to be a widespread belief
that reliance upon uncompensated work “has encouraged ‘corrupt’ practices
very similar to those in political life.” Thus, the network is now advo-cating
adoption of the following additional principle: · In the Economy
of Solidarity nothing is wasted, nothing is volunteered, e v e rything
is recycled, everything must be paid for, and everything is divided in
equal conditions! P roblems and Pro s p e c t s It should come as no surprise
that a complex organization that has grown so large and so fast should
manifest some diffi-culties. The autonomy of the various clubs has resulted
in a plethora of local currencies issued in a variety of ways, some of
which may be questionable from the standpoint of strict reciprocity. Some
of the larger issuers are unable to give a proper accounting of all the
notes they have issued. While a strong desire exists among the various
clubs in the network to accept each other’s notes, concerns and uncertainties
have led some nodos to refuse to accept the notes of others, causing some
confusion and dismay among the people. Adding to the confusion is the actuality
of counterfeiting. This is the first real counterfeiting of a community
currency that has come to my attention. C o u n t e rfeit versions of at
least one of the larger note issues have been injected into the network.
This does not seem to have done significant harm, since their number has
been small and the counterfeit notes are not very difficult to distinguish
from the genuine ones. What happens when someone discov-ers that they have
accepted a counterfeit note? Practice varies. Sometimes the person will
simply pass it along, but quite often the local club or the issuing club
will destroy the note and absorb the loss rather than force the holder
to take the loss. Another developing problem is the emergence of political
factionalism and a struggle for leadership within the movement. One faction
is attempting to become the spokesman for the entire network and wants
to replace the various local currencies with its own currency to be used
throughout the country. This faction, led by the founders of the first
Barter Club, is the one that signed Recent Models and Developments 63.the
agreement with the Argentine government. Another faction is seriously concerned
about preserving the autonomy of the local clubs and wants to negotiate
a consensus about the critical issues facing the movement, but the first
faction is not willing to participate. It will be interesting to see how
this conflict plays out over the coming year or two. If the network is
to avoid disintegration, the various clubs will need to come to some clear
agreement on standards of practice for the proper issuance and management
of their currencies. 64 M O N E Y.P A R T I I I M O N E TARY TRA NS F O
R M AT I O N AND CO M M U N I T Y E M P O W E R M EN T < I n this part
of the book we get into the particulars of money and the design elements
of cooperative exchange systems and com-munity currencies—the essential
features, the forms and devices, the procedures and methodologies. Part
3 includes, in chapter 13, a primer on mutual credit, which is the foundation
on which any pri-vate exchange system should be built. It addresses the
major issues in currency design—such as basis of issue, backing, credit
and debit limits, system revenues and costs, savings and investment—and
tackles the thorny question of usury and interest. 12. Currency Fundamentals
127 Basis of Issue 128 Regulation of the Amount of Exchange Media Supplied
128 Power to Issue 129 What Gives a Currency Credibility? 130 Forms and
Devices 134.Chapter 13 < Mu t u a l C r e d i t : T he Foun d a t i
on f o r C o mmun i t y C u r r e n c i e s The composite credit of private
competitive traders, based as it is, upon actual exchange of goods and
services, forms the only substance of money. —E. C. Riegel T he p urp os
e of e ve ry community currency or exchange system is to provide a payment
medium that is separate from, and supplemental to, official money, and
that originates not in banks or government but in the community of members.
What do the members have to offer one another in exchange for their goods
and services? Only their own goods and serv i c e s . U l t i m a t e l
y, we each have only one currency with which to pay, and that is our own
production. What is needed is some device, a “placeholder,” if you will,
that allows both time and opportunity for accounts to be balanced. All
that this requires is a willingness to wait and a willingness to trust.
In a word, the members of the trading community must be willing to give
each other “ c r e d i t . ” Wha t I s Mu t ua l C r e di t ? Mutual credit
is the essential agreement that underlies any complementary exchange system
or community currency. Any community currency that is not based on a clear
agreement among those who are empowered to issue it will be d i fficult
to manage and prone to failure . Just as your dollars can be held in the
form of either Federal Reserve notes or account balances in a bank or.credit
union, so too can community currencies take the form of either paper notes
or account balances. A community exchange system may utilize any of the
various financial instruments and protocols with which we are already familiar.
It may utilize physical objects that circulate from hand to hand, such
as paper notes, coins, or tokens; it may be comprised of accounts and ledgers
on which debits and credits are recorded; or it may involve some combina-tion
of these. Whatever form the exchange media may take, whether paper notes
or account balances, the same basic principles apply. Therefore, when we
speak of “currency,” it should be understood that the term also includes
credits in a ledger (bookkeeping) system. Further, it should be pointed
out that while accounts may be kept on a computer, a ledger system can
be as sim-ple as a pen and a notebook. Mutual cre d i t is the generic
term that we use to describe an association of traders who have agreed
to create and utilize their own exchange medium. Anyone familiar with LETS,
described in chapter 10, already has a basic under-standing of what mutual
credit looks like. LETS is a particular type or “brand” of mutual credit.
It has its own particular procedures and protocols. A mutual credit system
might, like LETS, use a ledger or system of accounts for record-ing the
trades and tracking the account balances of its members, but it might also
utilize circulating notes. These notes can be issued to members against
their credit lines, in effect providing a physical representation of that
credit. Just as a cash withdrawal is debited against (subtracted from)
a bank account, the amount of any notes thus issued would be debited against
the members’ mutual credit account. Indeed, the use of circulating notes
may be employed to eliminate completely the need to record members’ transactions.
The pass-ing of notes from hand to hand is just an alternative way of keeping
score in the economic game of give and take. This is the path that Tucson
Traders has elected to take, as described in chapter 11. A mutual credit
system is designed to surmount the limitations of barter. Like money, it
provides an intermediary device that allows two parties to trade even though
one of them may have nothing the other wants. For example, sup-pose Martha
knits sweaters and John wants to buy one but has nothing that Martha presently
needs. Using mutual credit, John can still get the sweater by giving Martha
“credits” for the agreed price. Where does John get the credits to give
to Martha? He creates them. Just as banks create dollars to give to someone
who requests a loan, John creates the credits to pay Martha for the s w
e a t e r. Martha can then spend those credits when she buys something
from anyone else in the system. When John creates credits to pay Martha,
he obli-gates himself to accept credits from someone in the system at some
future time in payment for his own goods or services. In this way, by making
a sale, he “redeems” the credits that he originally issued. This is shown
pictorially in fig-ure 13.1. It can be seen that the process is essentially
identical to that of the Mutual Credit 67.68 M O N E Y ideal money circuit
described in chapter 4 and to the LETS trading circuit described in chapter
10. In a mutual credit system, the members empower themselves to do the
same thing that banks have done for years, essentially creating their own
money in the form of credit but saving the cost of interest, while distributing
the money themselves according to their own needs. In such a system, hold-ing
credits is evidence that so much value has been delivered to the commu-n
i t y, while a debit balance indicates that a member has received that
much more from the community than she or he has delivered. A debit balance
thus represents a person’s commitment to deliver that much value to the
commu-nity sometime in the near future. H ow a Mu t ua l Cr e di t S ys
t e m Wo r k s Mutual credit can be viewed as an extension of the long-established
practice of the trade credit that businesses offer to one another in the
normal course of business. Businesses often sell to their customers on
what is called “open account,” which means that they deliver the merchandise
and bill their cus-tomers for the amount due. A certain amount of time
is allowed for payment to be made. It may be fifteen, thirty, sixty days
or more, depending on the customs and needs of that particular line of
business. Often, a discount may be given for prompt payment. In the terminology
of business, an example of typ-ical trade terms might be “2%/10; net 30
days,” which means that payment is due within thirty days of the billing
date, but a 2 percent discount may be taken if payment is made within ten
days. The basic idea of a mutual credit system is to extend the practice
of trade credit to a wider group of participants, each of whom has the
power to buy without cash and, at the same time, to lengthen the duration
within which bal-ances may be outstanding. The ideal, at least with respect
to empowerment of the participants and local control of the local economy,
is to eliminate com-pletely the requirement of payment in official currency.
In actual practice, the exchange of goods and services within a mutual
credit system involves the payment of some combination of community credits
and official cash. Since a seller must usually incur some cash costs in
providing goods or services to the buyer, she or he must be able to earn
enough cash to cover those costs. Over the long run, individual mutual
credit account balances will move up and down, some months ending with
a credit balance and some months end-ing with a debit balance, but averaging
out around a balance of zero. As long as debit balances do not become chronic
or extreme, the system can handle these situations readily. Indeed, since
the total of credits in the system must be balanced by an equal amount
of total debits, outstanding debit balances are a necessary feature of
the system and will have no adverse effect on its opera-.Figure 13.1. The
mutual credit trading circuit. Credits Credits Credits Credits Goods/ Services
Goods/ Services Goods/ Services Goods/ Services Mr. Able Issuer Ms. Zane
Mr. Cook Mr. Young Ms. Drew Credits Goods/Services Mr. Baker Credits Goods/Services.tion.
If a particular participant develops a chronic debit balance, steps can
be taken by the group to help him or her to increase sales and/or reduce
pur-chases. This may involve retraining or the kind of friendly assistance
that is typ-ical within mutual support networks. B as i c S t e ps i n
Or g a n i z i n g a Mu t ual Cr e di t Sy s t e m Here, in brief, are
the essential steps involved in starting a mutual credit trad-ing system
(these will be elaborated upon in chapter 18): 1. Organize a core group
of people and organizations to begin trading among themselves using trade
credit units as the exchange medium. It is best if the founding group is
composed of people who already know and trust one another or who have some
affinity or common interest. The group can be expanded, as appropriate,
by inviting other friends, family, acquaintances, and business associates
to join. New members might be provisional for some specified period of
time, after which they would have the same status as founding members.
Provisional members might have a debit limit that is lower than the limit
for full members. Over time the membership can be made more inclusive,
but there needs to be a balance between system integrity and inclusivity.
2. Choose some unique name for the system credits to distinguish them from
official currency. They might be called “sand dollars,” “green dollars,”
“acorns,” “credits,” “tokens,” “hours,” and so forth. However, to avoid
con-fusion, I suggest that the use of the word d o l l a r be avoided in
naming the local unit. 3. Place a limit on debit balances in members’ accounts.
Initially, every full member account should have the same maximum debit
(negative) balance. The amount is arguable, but an equivalent of about
two hundred or three hundred dollars might be reasonable. As trading develops,
debit limits might be raised for those who demonstrate the capacity to
carry a higher amount by selling more within the system. A good rule of
thumb for set-ting debit limits is that a person’s debit limit should be
no more than two or three times his or her average monthly community credit
sales. 4. Designate someone to assume the role of “registrar” for the system,
to main-tain the account ledger and membership list. The accounts can be
kept as pages in a notebook, on file cards, or on a computer. The registrar
will record transactions (debits and credits), update members’ account
bal-ances, and periodically issue account statements. Members can report
their transactions using a standard form similar to a check, or transactions
can be reported to a telephone answering machine. The simplest accounting
sys-tem is a loose-leaf notebook that contains a page for each member.
The 70 M O N E Y.page should contain spaces for transactions to be recorded,
columns for debits and credits, and a column for the running balance. Periodic
account statements could consist simply of a photocopy of each member’s
page. Such an account page as used by Tucson Traders was shown in chapter
11 (figure 11.1). Figure 13.2 shows a typical mutual credit system check.
5. Produce and distribute at regular intervals a system status report showing
each member’s balance and trading volume. This will help to establish a
completely open information system and allow every member to know the health
of the system and be aware of any developing problems with chronic or excessive
balances. It might also highlight the identity of the most active and productive
participants. 6. Designate someone to produce a newsletter containing classified
ads listing both offers of, and requests for, goods and services. This
could be part of the registrar’s duties, or it could be done by someone
else. 7. Since the mutual credit system has operating expenses, it must
generate some revenue. This can be accomplished by charging fees for some
or all of the services provided. Fixed fees may be applied for such serv
i c e s as recording transactions, advertising offers and requests, and
generat-ing and mailing account statements and reports. Some of these fees
can be in system credits, but some are needed in official currency to cover
costs such as postage, printing, or supplies that cannot be obtained within
the system. These cash expenses might also be covered by an annual membership
fee. 8. Schedule regular gatherings of the membership. These are useful
not only to take care of system business but to get to know one another,
to trade, and to have some fun. Try potluck suppers, fairs, trading bazaars,
celebrations, picnics, auctions, and rummage sales. Thomas A. Trader Member
Number 1066 P.O. Box 42663, Tucson, AZ 85733 Date: ___________ Credit the
Account of: ____________TT _____________ _________Tucson Tokens For ___________________Signed_________
Tucson Traders • P.O. Box 1842 • Tucson, Arizona, 85722 Figure 13.2. A
mutual credit system check. Mutual Credit 71.9. Consider the possibility
of charging a small percentage, in system credits, at the end of each quarter
or year on all balances, both credit and debit. The percentage charged
should be the same for both types of balance. This will have several positive
effects. It is intended mainly to stimulate the cir-culation of credits
and avoid stagnation of balances. In addition, it will provide a supplementary
source of system credits with which to pay for sys-tem operation and development.
This will assure more adequate compen-sation for the registrar, newsletter
editor, and others who provide services to the system. Any surpluses that
develop might be used to fund community projects or for other purposes
that the members determine by consensus. (This item is among the more controversial
issues in mutual credit and will be discussed further in chapters 15 and
18.) As the mutual credit system develops, members will likely find that
they are supporting one another in a variety of ways—as friends, confidants,
coun-selors, and more. Some direct barter and informal trading will occur.
This should be encouraged rather than discouraged. Even though private
and informal transactions bypass the system and avoid paying fees into
it, they also reduce the workload. The primary objective, after all, is
to foster the devel-opment of mutually supportive relationships. If the
system works for people, they will help to maintain it through donations
and volunteer labor. S o m e-times it’s better not to keep score. C o n
ti n u i n g I ss u e s i n Mut u al C r e di t Sy s t e m s This chapter
is intended to provide a quick overview of mutual credit. The steps and
suggestions outlined above are by no means the final word on the matter
and will be looked at in later chapters. Each group will have to work out
for itself many of the answers to the recurrent problems of exchange, but
full advantage should be taken of the experience of others. The questions
and issues that need to be addressed in establishing and operating a mutual
credit system are essentially the same as those which exist in any system
of money and banking, and if not properly handled can lead to disastrous
con-sequences. Various groups have dealt with them in different ways, but
some approaches are superior to others. Here are some of the major issues
that need to be highlighted: Debit Limits How are limits on individual
accounts to be set? What amounts are reason-able in allowing members maximum
purchasing power without becoming a drag on the system? What provisions
should be made for monitoring accounts, preventing overdrafts, and correcting
imbalances? 72 M O N E Y.Account settlement agreements How long should
account balances be allowed to remain stagnant? What should be done when
a member drops out? What provisions, if any, should be made for periodic
clearing or settlement of accounts? S avings and Investment Prov i s i
o n s What if people want to save some of their credits over extended periods
of time? Can that be accommodated without diminishing the effectiveness
of mutual credit as a medium of exchange? If not, what mechanisms should
be used to limit the use of mutual credit as a savings and investment medium?
Interest/Demurrage on Account Balances Should interest and/or demurrage
charges be levied on debit and/or credit balances? Coresponsibility Gro
u p s Should membership be completely open or should it be required that
new members be sponsored by existing members? Should participation be based
on individual membership or should everyone be part of an affinity group
in which the group members take some responsibility for each others’ balances?
G ro u p / O r g a n i z at i o n a l / Fa m i ly Memberships Should the
system provide fee discounts to people who join as part of an organization,
group, or family, and if so how much? How is “family” defined? What limitations
should be placed on family or group memberships, if any? Ta x a b i l i
t y / R e p o rta b i l i t y There is a considerable amount of confusion
and controversy about whether cashless trading is taxable, either constitutionally
or under IRS regulations, and whether or not members need to report their
trading on their tax returns. If trades are reported, should the seller
report the credits she or he received, or should the buyer report the value
of the goods and services received? Which party has received income? Is
the system administrator responsible for report-ing members’ business transactions
to the IRS or other tax authorities? A dv e rtising and Tr a n s action
Fees How much should be charged for publishing notices/ads and recording
trans-actions? What portion of the charges should be charged in official
currency and what portion in system credits? How can meeting the general
cash needs for operating the system be assured? Mutual Credit 73.S t ra
t e g i e s f or E nha n c i n g Mut ua l Cr e di t Sys t ems a n d Ga
i n i n g A c c e pt a n c e Many community exchange systems begin with
a flurry of enthusiasm and then gradually grind to a halt. Here are some
suggestions for improving the likeli-hood of sustained success. 1. Utilize
familiar financial devices such as notes or tokens, checks, and credit/debit
cards to facilitate exchange transactions and provide more reli-able accounting.
Most mutual credit systems, like LETS, rely mainly on tele-phone reporting
as the basis for updating member accounts. While that may be perfectly
adequate for small systems, larger systems may require a more foolproof
recording process and a paper trail for verification. 2. Involve as many
established businesses as possible, especially locally owned retail establishments
that potential members are accustomed to patroniz-ing. The participation
of established businesses provides a mutual credit sys-tem with instant
credibility and makes the system more useful to potential members. Effort
should be made to help retail businesses find ways to spend their community
currency income. 3. Hold frequent trading fairs or bazaars to bring members
together for the purpose of trading, socializing, and celebrating. Schools,
community cen-ters, church halls, and parks can often be obtained at no
cost or low cost for such activities. These events must be well organized
and well publicized to be effective. Low attendance can be demoralizing
and inhibit attendance at subsequent events. 4. Establish some form of
community store that enables members to buy and sell their goods and services
for local currency. The store should operate in a familiar organized retail
setting with more or less regular business hours. Such a “cooperative”
gives members with low sales volume an outlet for their goods without having
to incur prohibitive overhead expenses. It also encourages more habitual
trading. 5. Make a special effort to involve marginalized and underutilized
groups, for instance retirees and youth, who have lots of time and/or less
than ade-quate money income. These groups have a greater need for exchange
alter-natives and are able to devote more time and effort to making trades
and helping to run the system. 6. Enlist the support and encouragement
of government officials, especially at the local level, and of the private
nonprofit sector, especially social serv i c e providers, but be sure to
maintain control in the hands of a volunteer core. Be careful when dealing
with bureaucracies: they can take up a lot of your time and energy in futile
activity. 74 M O N E Y.14. Basic Currency Types: A Classification Scheme
145 Different Breeds of Cat: Community Currencies Are Not All Created Equal
145 Good Paper vs. Bad Paper 146 Types of Currencies 146 Sidebar: Harvey
Bucks 158 15. A Note on Interest 164 Interest or Usury? 165 Toward Better
Forms of Exchange 167 What about Charges on Credit Balances? 167 Sidebar:
A Story of Robinson Crusoe 168 16. Medium of Exchange or Savings Medium?
172 Conflicting Roles of Money 172 Saving and Investment 173 How Do We
Save? 173 Preventing Stagnation in Mutual Credit Systems 174 Current Account
vs. Capital Account 175 Sidebar: Mutual Credit Loans: An Example 176 Interest
Revisited 176 Basis of Issue Revisited 177.P A R T I V C U R R EN CY DES
I GN, I M P RO V E M EN T, AND I N N O VAT I O N < I n addressing the
megacrisis that confronts the world today, it should be clear that decisive
changes will need to made in the methods we humans use to distribute political/economic
power and allocate material re s o u rc e s . As pointed out earlier, the
present dominant stru c t u res of money and finance, by their very nature,
promote the concentration of power into fewer and fewer hands, increase
disparities in the distribution of wealth, channel a huge portion of the
eart h ’s re s o u rces into wasteful production, and forc e both social
and ecological degradation. The pinnacle of power today is the power to
issue money. If that power can be democratized and focused in a d i rection
that gives social and ecological concerns top priority, there may yet be
hope for saving the world. This section is a how-to-do-it guide. It contains
a number of innovative p roposals for achieving nothing less than world-saving
re f o rms. All these proposals involve the use of community currencies
to facilitate trade within local communities, and many of them also contain
features for the empow-e rment of community improvement groups working
to serve the common good. These proposals are described mainly in terms
of circulating notes or c e rtificates, but, as already stressed, exchange
media could also take the f o rm of accounting credits on a ledger. In
fact any of the various devices such as notes, checks, smart cards, and
debit cards may be used to trans-fer credits. The proposals described here
could also be applied to empow-ering groups whose members are widely dispersed
geographically, using the Internet and our highly developed information
and communications infra-structure. The basis of issuing money has, in
times past, been more neutral than at p resent. Now, with the issuance
of money controlled by the central bank/central government nexus, it has
become a mechanism by which these centralized powers control the application
of human and capital re s o u rces, allocating them to projects that are
usually self-serving, waste-ful of re s o u rces, and often downright destructive.
Our objective should be to c reate exchange media issued on the basis of
human service and Earth serv-ice rather than acquisitiveness and domination.
The exchange media described in this section put control of the exchange
process into the hands of the people, giving them more choice.over how
they apply their energies and re s o u rces. The willingness of oth-ers
in the community to accept the new exchange media in payment for goods
and services, especially the necessities of life, does two things: it encourages
the application of people’s energies and re s o u rces to life-sus-taining
activities, and it provides the community with a medium of exchange that
by its very nature is abundant, democratic, and locally controlled. Any
community, at any time, could implement the following model cur-rency systems,
with beneficial effects. The descriptions given here are “bare-bones” outlines.
The precise details can be tailored to the needs and circumstances of the
particular community. 17. Improving Local Currencies, or How to Make a
Good Thing Better 181 Gift Exchange vs. Reciprocal Exchange 182 Money Is
an IOU 182 Basis of Issue 183 Mutual Credit and Paper Notes 183 Essential
Differences between LETS and HOURS 183 How HOURS Work 184 Fish or Fowl?
185 How Are Ithaca HOURS Issued? 189 Adding a Capital Cushion 191 Using
Excess Business Capacity to Support Local Currency 191 Combined Bases of
Issue 195 18. How to Design and Implement a Community Exchange System 197
Summary Prescription 198 Detailed Guidelines 199 Conclusion 212 19. A Business-Based
Community Currency 213 Community Trading Coupons 214 20. Currency Alternatives
for Impersonal Markets 220 Grain Banks and a Commodity-Based Currency 221
Comparison to Conventional Money 224 21. Good Money for Good Work 227 Community
Service Coupons 227 Earth Rescue Receipts (ERRs) 232 Sidebar: ERR Questions
and Answers 234 Funded Temporary Receipts (FTRs) 236 Sidebar: FTR Questions
and Answers 239.Chapter 22 < Yo ut h E mp l o y me nt Sc r i p ( Y E
S) . . . one sixth of all 16- to 24-year olds in America—mostly males—are
currently “disaffected and disconnected.” They are not associated with
any formal role in society, nor are they in any formal relationship with
another person. —David Pearce Snyder Y ES I S A N A C R O N Y M that stands
for both Youth Employment Service and Youth Employment Scrip. I have been
promoting the YES project for the past several years. It is an application
of the community currency concept that pro-vides a way of mobilizing idle
resources, in this case the labor and talents of young people, to serve
community needs. Youth can be employed in either the private s e c t o
r, or the public sector; in for-profit business or nonprofit organizations.
YES acknowledges the value of the services they render, without the payment
of scarce federal money. Instead, the Youth Employment Service issues Yo
u t h Employment Scrip as a way of paying young people for the work that
they do. 1 YES provides a supplemental supply of local currency, which
businesses and individuals in the community agree to accept in partial
or full payment for the goods and services they sell. The Youth Employment
Service, which issues the scrip, then accepts it from others in payment
for the services it provides. This approach does not depend on either tax
revenues or charity. Rather, it simply provides the missing element required
to bring people who need income together with work that needs to be done.
That missing element is m o n e y. Complementary exchange mechanisms such
as scrip have shown them-selves to be viable and acceptable substitutes
for official money. The YES pro-gram empowers youth, supports the local
economy, finances important work, and helps to unify the community..The
Yo u t h Pro b l e m Young people are increasingly seen by the general
community as a problem. A large percentage of crimes are committed by young
people, and about one-quarter of our prison population is under age twenty-five.
But crime is just the most extreme aspect of the problem. There are even
greater numbers who do not become criminal but who are alienated and hopeless.
Lacking self-esteem and basic social and employment skills, they ultimately
become non-contributing citizens, immature adults, and ineffective parents.
It is both callous and naive to think that police and prisons can contain
the effects of the increasing alienation of youth and other marginalized
groups. The young are our future. It is in every o n e ’s interest to invest
in their preparation and development and to help integrate them into society
and the economy—to help them become capable, responsible, and successful,
with an adequate degree of self-esteem, and thus able to direct their own
lives. The question is how to do that most effectively. The experience
of recent years has demon-strated that spending more money on schools and
prisons is probably not the answer. The “system” has rendered young people
nonessential to the community, diminishing the well-being of both. Increasingly,
adults perceive youths as trou-blesome, inadequate “others,” which reflects
back on how the youths perceive themselves. What young people need most
is a sense of belonging. The attrac-tion of gang membership is that it
provides young people with an identity at a time in their lives when a
primary issue is figuring out who they are and how they fit into the wider
world. They especially need to have meaningful work and their own sources
of income so that they can become independent and self-responsible as they
grow into adulthood. Peter Schwartz, president of the Global Business Network,
wrote a book in 1991 titled The Art of the Long View (Doubleday). In that
book he predicted that, by the year 2000, the earth’s population would
include more than two billion people between the ages of ten and twenty-one,
about one-third of the total population. That prediction has proven to
be correct. Schwartz devoted an entire chapter to the phenomenon of “the
global teenager,” a force that he says will dwarf other demographic factors
over the next fifty years. The pres-sure of their numbers, energy, and
idealism, he wrote, “will be so immense that it will reshape the world.”
Schwartz pointed out that “in the past, societies with large numbers of
ado-lescent males started wars.” According to Gerald Smith, professor of
religion and ecology at the University of the South in Sewanee, Tennessee,
the youth population of Iran and Iraq rose to 50 percent before the Iran-Iraq
war. That war killed millions of young males. Whether or not it was intentional,
the war Youth Employment Scrip (YES) 79.managed to relieve much of the
political and economic pressure deriving from the explosion of the youth
population in those countries. Without the experience of being needed and
responsible for their com-munities, and without adequate incomes, the young,
as a group, can be expected to express their insecurity and alienation
in criminal, antisocial, and self-destructive behavior. Suicide among young
people is their leading cause of death. 2 Being largely left out of the
mainstream economy, youths find power where they can—in gang membership
and commerce in illicit substances. The misguided “war on drugs” is mainly
a war against youth and minorities. Older people seem to have little understanding
of youth culture and motivations and are all too ready to support “get
tough” policies, which lead mainly to further alienation and a mushrooming
rate of incarceration for nonviolent “crimes.” This situation can only
become worse if current eco-nomic trends and government policies continue.
It will take extensive restruc-turing of our economic institutions and
methods of allocating wealth in order to defuse this time bomb. We must
find ways to integrate the young more effectively into society. We m u
s t p r o v i d e t h e m w i t h m e a n i n g f u l w o r k t h a t i
s b o t h e d i f y i n g f o r t h e m a n d v a l u a b l e t o t h e
c o m m u n i t y. C l e a r l y t h e r e i s n o e n d o f w o r k n
e e d i n g t o b e done. It is equally evident that the vast majority
of young people are eager to work. What often is missing is the money to
bring work and worker together. I n t h e p r i v a t e s e c t o r, b
u s i n e s s e s n e e d t o k e e p c o s t s d o w n i n o r d e r t
o c o m-p e t e i n t o d a y ’s g l o b a l e c o n o m y. T h e i r i
n c e n t i v e s a r e t o m i n i m i z e t h e n u m-b e r o f p e o
p l e t h e y e m p l o y a n d t h e a m o u n t t h e y p a y i n w a
g e s , s a l a r i e s , a n d b e n e f i t s . A s t h e p a c e o f
a u t o m a t i o n c o n t i n u e s t o a c c e l e r a t e , t h e r
e w i l l b e a n i n c r e a s i n g g a p b e t w e e n t h e n u m b
e r o f j o b s a n d t h e n u m b e r o f p e o p l e s e e k i n g e
m p l o y m e n t . I n t h e p u b l i c s e c t o r, t h e r e i s p
r e s s u r e o n a l l l e v e l s o f g o v-e r n m e n t t o k e e p
c o s t s a n d t a x e s d o w n . W i t h i n c r e a s i n g g o v e
r n m e n t i n d e b t-e d n e s s a n d i n t e r e s t p a y m e n t
s e a t i n g u p a n e v e r i n c r e a s i n g p o r t i o n o f t h
e i r b u d g e t s , a n d w i t h m o r e m o n e y b e i n g s p e n
t o n a d i r e c t b u t f u t i l e a t t a c k o n c r i m e , g o v
e r n m e n t a l b o d i e s a r e c u t t i n g b a c k o n s o c i a
l p r o g r a m s a n d r e l e a s i n g employees. The socialistic approaches,
which have been dominant since the Great Depression and Franklin Delano
Roosevelt, have proven to be woefully 80 M O N E Y C learly there is no
end of work needing to be done. It is equally evident that the vast majority
of young people are eager to work. What often is missing is the money to
bring work and worker together..inadequate. Bureaucratic programs, funded
and administered by distant gov-ernment agencies, cannot begin to solve
problems that are inherently spiritual, interpersonal, and local. Indeed,
such programs often perpetuate or exacer-bate the problems they are intended
to solve. One principle seems clear. Those closest to a problem are best
equipped to solve it. Effective solutions to community problems can be
found only at the community level. The first thing to do is to change our
attitudes and shift our focus—away from Washington, away from the state
capital, and back to our-selves, our neighborhoods, and our communities.
The Mon e y Pr o b l e m Lack of money is the usual reason given for problems
not being addressed. Ye t , as described earlier, official money is kept
purposely scarce in the mistaken belief that scarcity is what gives money
its value. As a result, the official mone-t a ry system does not provide
an adequate supply of money to allow for a fair distribution of the products
of the economy, or even to provide everyone with a subsistence level of
income. Monetary scarcity also makes it possible for money to be “lent”
at high rates of interest and enables those who control its creation to
determine the course of the economy and the financial fate of the people.
The tragic result is that important work remains undone and human needs
often go unmet because of the lack of money. This scarcity is felt most
acutely at the margins of society, by those who are less well connected
and whose skills are least valued by the market economy. Their numbers
include an ever growing proportion of young people. This situation can,
and must, be remedied. As shown throughout this book, money is a human
creation. It is just a medium of exchange. Why should money ever be too
scarce to match idle workers with work that needs to be done? We can restore
the integrity of our local economies, which will, in turn, go a long way
toward solving our social and environmental problems. As argued throughout
this book, one way to do this is to create our own local medium of exchange
to supplement scarce national currency. This has been done many times before,
and it is being done now in many places around the world. A local currency
can provide the means of connecting buyers and sell-ers who would otherwise
be kept apart by lack of money. Young people can thus be reconnected to
the community and brought into the economy as productive members, learning
important skills, building self-esteem, and earning the income that they
need to begin to become self-supporting. This can be accomplished by voluntary
local action without the need for new legislation or government financing,
by using local currency scrip as the bridge. Youth Employment Scrip (YES)
81.82 M O N E Y H ow Do e s t he YE S Pr o g ra m Wo r k ? The project
hub is a central coordinating body that we call the Youth Employ-ment Service
or yesXchange. It could be a nonprofit organization or govern-ment agency
or even a private, for-profit business. This coordinating body plays several
roles: · It acts as an employment agency, placing young people in
jobs. · It plays the role of a “bank,” issuing and redeeming scrip.
· It acts as a trade exchange, helping to broker trades between
participating businesses. · It collaborates with other agencies
in arranging for training, counseling, and other forms of worker support.
The coordinating body can function much like a temporary employment a g
e n c y, except that, in this case, all the employees are young people
within a certain age range and are paid in scrip instead of (or in addition
to) official money. The client businesses and agencies needing temporary
employees pay their fees to the yesXchange partly in YEScrip and partly
in cash. The cash part allows the yesXchange to meet that portion of its
overhead expenses that can only be paid in cash and to provide a partial
cash wage to the youths it employs. In order to assure the value and continued
acceptability of the scrip, the yesX-change must be willing to accept its
own scrip in payment of its fees, at par with official currency. A YEScrip
unit is equivalent to one dollar’s worth of service. Businesses can earn
YEScrip by accepting it in trade, either from individuals who have earned
it by working for the Youth Employment Service or from other busi-nesses
that have accepted it in trade. The businesses can then use the YEScrip
to pay for work done by young workers. Businesses, by accepting YEScrip
in partial payment for their goods and services, stimulate their own business
just as their use of a discount coupon does. But unlike a discount coupon,
YES notes can be passed along (spent) for value or donated to promote activities
of benefit to the community. T h e f o l l o w i n g e x a m p l e d e
m o n s t r a t e s t h e p r o c e s s b y w h i c h s c r i p i s i s
s u e d , c i r c u l a t e d , a n d r e d e e m e d . I t i s s h o w
n p i c t o r i a l l y i n f i g u r e 2 2 . 1 . T h e Y E S c r i p h
a s t o b e g i n s o m e w h e r e , a n d i n t h i s c a s e i t i s
i s s u e d b y t h e Yo u t h E m p l o y m e n t S e rv i c e . S u p
p o s e t h e B e r r y F a r m n e e d s h e l p h a rv e s t i n g i
t s s t r a w b e r ry c r o p . T h e o w n e r c a l l s t h e y e s
X c h a n g e , w h i c h a g r e e s t o s e n d C a r o l y n o u t t
o p i c k b e r r i e s . A t t h e e n d o f t h e w e e k , C a r o l
y n s u b m i t s h e r s i g n e d t i m e s h e e t t o t h e y e s X
c h a n g e , a n d i t g i v e s C a r o l y n n e w l y i s s u e d Y
E S c r i p a s p a y f o r h e r w o r k ..Figure 22.1. Youth Employment
Scrip circuit. Dress Scrip Scrip Groceries Scrip Scrip Issued Scrip Redeemed
Strawberries Lighting Installation Labor Services Youth Employment Service
Youth Worker Berry Farm Dress Shop Coop Grocery Electrician.What good is
the YEScrip to Carolyn? The yesXchange has persuaded several local businesses
to accept YEScrip in payment for the goods and services they sell. The
Dress Shop is one of them. So Carolyn spends her scrip to buy a new dress.
The Dress Shop, in turn, hires an electrician to install new lighting fix-tures.
The electrician then spends the YEScrip on groceries at the Coop Gro-c
e ry Store, which uses it to buy strawberries from the Berry Farm. The
Berry Farm uses the YEScrip to pay what it owes to the Youth Employment
Serv i c e for Carolyn’s labor. The Youth Employment Service retires the
scrip until more work is done. Now the scrip has come full circle. It was
issued by the YEServ i c e when it paid Carolyn on behalf of the Berry
Farm, and it was redeemed by the Y E S e rvice when it was accepted from
the Berry Farm in payment of its debt to the service. Note that the scrip
could have changed hands any number of times before making its way back
to the Berry Farm and the yesXchange. For the sake of clarity and simplicity,
this example has shown just a few transactions. In practice, each transaction
might involve some combination of scrip and official money. The Dress Shop,
for example might be willing to accept 50 percent of the price of any merchandise
in YEScrip and require the other 50 percent in official money. Thus, Carolyn
could buy a $40 dress by paying Y20 (Y is the symbol for YEScrip) and $20.
The Dress Shop now has $20, which it can use to cover its cash costs; it
also has Y20, which it can use to hire the elec-trician, who might also
require some cash to cover cash costs. But since the e l e c t r i c i
a n ’s cash expenses are lower, he or she might be willing to accept 80
percent of fees in YEScrip and 20 percent in official money. Be n e f i
ts of t he YE S Pr o j e c t The implementation of such a project results
in several positive effects: 1. It helps to empower a marginalized group
of citizens (youths) and make them stakeholders in the community by integrating
them into the local economy. 2. It supports the local economy by providing
a supplemental local currency to facilitate trade—trade which in many instances
could not otherwise take place. Since scrip is recognized only within the
local community, this sup-plemental currency favors local goods and services
over imports. 3. It provides a means of financing work that serves the
common good, improves the quality of life, and enhances the health of the
community. 4. It unifies the community in an effort in which everybody
wins. YEScrip provides an exchange medium issued on the basis of effort
put forth by youthful workers, effort that can be applied to commercial
enterprises, human service, and/or community improvement. It is completely
sound 84 M O N E Y.because it is firmly based on the exchange of real value.
Although Yo u t h Employment Scrip is described in terms of circulating
certificates or notes, it could also take the form of credits in an electronic
system using “smart cards” or debit cards or some combination of accounting
credits and circulating notes. I nvo l v i n g Lo c a l Bu s i n e ss e
s Merchants should be willing to accept YEScrip, not only because of its
bene-fits to the community, but also because it will help them to attract
a greater total amount of business and utilize some of their excess capacity.
As pointed out earlier, accepting a community currency can stimulate a
merchant’s busi-ness just as discount coupons do, while avoiding most of
the costs associated with a coupon campaign. Sometimes the use of a coupon
is restricted to assure that it will be used in a way that takes advantage
of a business’s excess capacity and will not draw away existing cash business.
A movie theater, for example, may accept coupons only for matinee performances
when the house is typically only partly filled, or a restaurant may honor
coupons only at particular (slack) hours and on slow days, and airlines
may honor coupons on a “space available” basis only. Like a discount coupon,
YEScrip gives a participating business a competitive advantage, but, unlike
a coupon, accepting YEScrip costs the business little or nothing because
the merchant can, in turn, spend it for something that he or she needs.
The key difference between YEScrip and a discount coupon is that businesses
agree to accept YEScrip not only from the public but also from each o t
h e r, and while a coupon is accepted only once and then canceled and dis-carded,
scrip can change hands, just like cash, any number of times. Each business
agrees to accept payment partly in cash and partly in YEScrip, with each
business itself deciding what percentage of the selling price to accept
in YEScrip. This percentage should be based on the cash costs and value
added of the particular business. The cash portion allows cash costs to
be met, while all or part of the value added by a business can be received
in scrip. The per-centage of the price that each business is willing to
accept in scrip can be adver-tised and posted on the premises. As an example,
the Pizza Parlor might advertise, “We accept YEScrip for up to 50 percent
of the purchase price on any pizza.” The issuance of currency at the local
level and the willingness of traders in the community to accept this supplemental
exchange medium in payment for goods and services, especially the necessities
of life, does two things: (1) it gives people more choice over the work
they choose to do, encouraging the application of their energies and resources
to activities consistent with their values, and (2) it provides the community
with a sound medium of exchange that by its very nature is abundant, democratic,
and locally controlled. Youth Employment Scrip (YES) 85.As the social and
economic benefits of such a program become more evi-dent, more and more
people will want to participate. Growing acceptance of the local exchange
medium will allow for the issuance of additional amounts, which will further
encourage work in the public interest. The resultant pros-perity should
also stimulate an increase in donations to the local nonprofit sec-tor
in general. Besides providing a local medium of exchange, YEScrip provides
a more participatory process for allocating the resources of the local
community, reducing the need for many government expenditures and trans-fer
payments. Eventually, most of the local merchants will jump onto the bandwagon
and accept YEScrip to attract their share of the available business, which
will have expanded because of the increased purchasing power that YEScrip
brings to the local economy. And, of course, those accepting a higher percentage
of pay-ment in YEScrip will probably attract more of the available business
than those accepting a lower percentage. P rog ra m Pa rt i c i p a n t
s an d A g re e m e n t s Besides the Youth Employment Service, which serves
as the hub and central coordinating body, three distinct groups participate
in the YES program. First there are the youth workers, whom we refer to
as work part n e r s . Second there are the businesses that hire the young
workers. These are called e m p l o y m e n t p a rt n e r s . The third
group is comprised of businesses that have agreed to accept scrip in full
or partial payment for the goods and services they sell. These are c a
l l e d trade part n e r s . Employment partners will normally also be
trade partners, since they are allowed to use scrip to pay their bills
to the YEService and thus have a particular reason (in addition to all
the community benefits) to earn some scrip income. Each of these “players”
in the program has a particular agreement that defines the terms and conditions
of their participation. These agreements must be carefully formulated,
clearly stated, and scrupulously adhered to. Participating businesses (employment
partners and trade partners) should have maximum freedom to set the terms
and limits of scrip acceptance and to be able to opt out of the program
at any time. Employment partners, how-e v e r, must pay whatever they owe
to the yesXchange for the value they received (in the form of youth labor).
If the program is properly run, businesses will cherish the opportunity
for continued participation. The greatest burden falls upon the yesXchange.
The most fundamental fea-ture of any currency issue is the commitment of
the issuer to accept it at full face value in payment for whatever the
issuer sells. In this case, the yesXchange must be willing at all times
to accept the scrip it issues in payment from its employment partners for
the youth labor provided. Thus, the basis of issue 86 M O N E Y.Announcement
Say Yes to Youth promote a healthy and prosperous community and a clean
environment announcing the Youth Employment Service (YES) and Youth Employment
Scrip (YES) The Youth Employment Service is a nonprofit service agency
devoted to the development and empowerment of our young people. All of
our workers are paid for their work using a form of "service credits" issued
as Youth Employment Scrip (YES). You can support our youth and at the same
time promote the local economy by accepting our scrip as you would your
own discount coupons, for, say, 20%, 30%, 50%, or more off your regular
prices. But unlike discount coupons, YES notes can be used by you to buy
things you need. You yourself can spend YES for goods and services offered
by other participating businesses, or you can use them to hire youth workers
to help you in your own business. Or you might pre-fer to donate YES to
any community improvement organization that you might wish to support.
Call today and let us add you to our list of participating businesses.
We will periodically publish this list, indicating for each business the
percentage of payment that it accepts in YES. The higher the percentage,
the more business you’ll attract. And remember, it costs you nothing, because
you, in turn, can spend the YES you accept. By accepting Youth Employment
Scrip, you’ll be helping our youth, our community, our local economy, and
yourself. With YES, Everybody Wins! Figure 22.2. Youth Employment Scrip
announcement..for Youth Employment Scrip is labor, and the “backing” for
it is the commit-ment of those who receive that labor to provide an equal
amount of value to the community in the form of goods and services, using
YEScrip as a vehicle. As pointed out above, YEScrip first enters circulation
when the YEServ i c e uses it to pay a worker. The service might validate
the scrip by signing and/or stamping it, and dating it (or dates could
be preprinted on the notes). The recipient of the scrip can then, in turn,
spend it on purchases from any par-ticipating merchant or anyone else willing
to accept it in payment. Thus, a YEScrip note can circulate as a supplemental
medium of exchange up to its expiration date, the holder being assured
that it will be accepted by, at the least, any employment partner or trade
partner. The benefits to the participating businesses are significant.
Instead of only competing with each other for whatever scarce official
money might be 88 M O N E Y Agreement (Name of business) agrees to accept
Youth Employment Scrip in partial payment for all products and services
that it offers, to the extent of ____% of the purchase price. Th Youth
Employment Service agrees to accept YES at full face value in payment for
all services that it customarily offers, to the extent of ____% of its
standard fees. This agreement may be canceled by either party at any time
upon writ-ten notice and payment of any outstanding balance. Signed_______Date
_____________ for (name of business) Signed__________Date _____________
for Youth Employment Service Figure 22.3. Youth Employment Scrip agreement..circulating
within the community, they would also be cooperating to supple-ment that
money with a local exchange medium, making it possible to transact a greater
amount of trade while also empowering the youths of the community. Since
the YEScrip has value only for purchases made locally, it remains in the
community instead of being used to buy from outside the community, tend-ing
to make the community more self-reliant and less dependent on export earnings.
A YES system might be started by publishing and distributing an announce-ment
like the one in figure 22.2. Each business would sign an agreement form
such as the one in figure 22.3. YES Questions and Answers < Q. Why would
anyone accept Youth Employment Scrip instead of official curre n c y ?
A. YEScrip will be acceptable for several reasons. (1) It will be an acceptable
f o rm of payment to young people who need work and are unable to find
employment that pays official money, because they know that they can spend
it at a variety of businesses in the community. (2) YEScrip will be acceptable
to businesses that wish to employ youths because they know that they can
use YEScrip to pay their wages. (3) YEScrip will appeal also to others
who s u p p o rt the activities that give rise to their issuance, namely
the employment of young people in meaningful work useful to the community
and private sec-t o r. (4) YEScrip will appeal to local merchants who can
see that accepting it will help to boost their cash business and strengthen
the entire local econ-omy. (5) It will be acceptable to anyone in the general
public who can see that YEScrip re p resents a sound medium of exchange
that can easily be spent in the community. Q. What will make YEScrip a
sound medium of exchange? A. YEScrip is not issued arbitrarily. It is issued
on the basis of valuable work done by the young workers. Each YES note,
there f o re, re p resents a receipt for actual value delivered. The amount
of YEScrip issued can never exceed the amount of labor value delivered.
A YES note will circulate only until some holder decides to pay it to the
Youth Employment Service for services rendered, or donates it to the service.
At that point the YES note will be re t i red from circulation until more
work is done to allow it to be reissued. Q. Won’t the issuance of YEScrip
cause inflation? A. A s p o i n t e d o u t i n t h e p re v i o u s c
h a p t e r, t h e i s s u a n c e o f Y E S c r i p , o r a n y o t h
e r c u rre n c y t h a t p e o p l e a re f re e t o d i s c o u n t o
r re f u s e , c a n n e v e r c a u s e i n f l a t i o n . S i n c e
Y E S c r i p n e e d n o t b e a c c e p t e d a t f a c e v a l u e b
y a n y o n e e x c e p t t h e i s s u-i n g a g e n c y, a n e x c e
s s o f Y E S c r i p i n c i rc u l a t i o n w i l l c a u s e i t t
o b e d i s c o u n t e d o r re f u s e d b y s e l l e r s i n t h e
m a r k e t . A s p e o p l e s e e t h i s h a p p e n i n g , t h e y
w i l l t e n d t o e a s e o ff o n t h e i r a c c e p t a n c e o f
i t , b e c a u s e t h e Y E S c r i p t h e y w o u l d re c e i v e
c o u l d n o t b e s p e n t f o r f u l l v a l u e . A t t h e o t h
e r e n d o f t h e l i n e , b u s i- Youth Employment Scrip (YES) 89.nesses
that buy labor from the Youth Employment Service will tend to accept more
YEScrip since they can thereby get workers more cheaply. For example, if
a one-dollar YES note is being accepted in the market at only eighty cents,
a b u s i n e s s t h a tu s e s Y E Ss e rv i c e s c a ng e t f i v e
d o l l a r sw o rt h o fl a b o r f o r Y E St h a t costs it only four
dollars. Whenever traders are free to discount the value of a n o t e ,
t h a t i s , a c c e p t i t a t l e s s t h a n f a c e v a l u e , t
h e m a r k e t w i l l a u t o m a t i c a l l y f o rc e t h e i s s
u i n g a u t h o r i t y t o a v o i d o v e r i s s u a n c e ; t h i
s m a k e s t h e c u rre n c y system self-adjusting. Q. Should YES be
issued in the form of accounting credits or paper notes? A. C o n c e p
t u a l l y, it doesn’t matter whether the YEScrip takes the form of paper
notes, tokens, or ledger balances (bookkeeping entries). These are all
sym-bolic re p resentations of the same thing—the values being exchanged—and
each is “backed” by the same commitment of the issuer to redeem the scrip
by providing value. So checks, notes, cards, and electronic transfers can
all be used interc h a n g e a b l y, as they are in the official monetary
system. Each form has its particular advantages, but paper notes are the
simplest form to imple-ment and handle. Q. What if a business accumulates
too much YEScrip? A. A local curre n c y, in its sole role of exchange
medium, should be spent as fast as it is taken in. If a participating business
finds insufficient opportunity to spend YEScrip on things that it needs,
the surplus would indicate that it over-estimated either (1) the value-added
portion of its selling price or (2) the will-ingness and/or ability of
others in the community to accept YEScrip. In either case, a business can
remedy the situation by reducing the percentage of YEScrip that it is willing
to accept in payment, giving it time to spend down its accumulated surplus
of YEScrip. Q. Should YEScrip have limited or perpetual life? A. Having
a periodic recall feature or expiration date is one way of addressing the
problem of keeping the YES notes an exchange medium and limiting their
use as a savings or “value storage” medium. As we have discussed pre v
i o u s l y, it is i m p o rtant to keep these two functions separate.
One way to do it is to have the local currency notes expire after a certain
length of time, say, one year. Mem-ber businesses might be allowed to exchange
expiring notes for new notes with a later expiration date. 90 M O N E Y.Epilogue
255 Appendix A: Note on Banking as a Profession, and Its Reform 257 Appendix
B: Note on the Proper Basis of Issue for Currency, and the Means of Financing
Capital Investments and Consumer Durables 260 Acknowledgments 263 Notes
264 References 274 Sources and Resources 277 Index 289.BOOK ORDERING INFORMAT
I O N < We are offering our e-book readers a special discount of 20%
on the bound book Money: Understanding and Creating Alternatives to Legal
Tender (296 pages, 6 x 9, paperback, appendices, notes, resources, index)
To order please contact: Chelsea Green Publishing PO Box 428 • Gates-Briggs
Building White River Junction, VT 05068 1-800-639-4099 or e-mail nhorster@chelseagreen.com
and mention the e-book $ 1 9.9 5 O N LY $15.9 5. |